The present invention relates generally to the field of Operations Research and Dynamic Programming (DP) of real-life decision problems such as product warranties. More particularly the present invention relates to flexible product warranties where customers can select and pay for warranty coverage on a monthly basis or on some other limited time period other than the customary annual or multi-year contracts.
As manufacturers (OEMs) face decreasing profit margins on sophisticated hardware products, post-sale services like extended warranties (EWs) are becoming increasingly important to an OEM's profitability. In addition to providing higher profit margins than typical hardware sales, EW service contracts help to extend the useful life of products, generate a profitable revenue stream of consumables and accessories over the lifetime of the original product, and provide an opportunity to improve customer loyalty whether the customer is an average consumer or another business entity. But many customers along with consumer rating agencies often view EWs as offering poor value to customers. This perception may be partly due to the fact that most warranties are offered at a uniform price regardless of how products are used, whether the products are for industrial or consumer usage, and are often only offered in increments of 1 to 3 years of coverage beyond the base-warranty period. This inflexible arrangement requires the customer to commit and pay for up-front costs for the entire warranty period. From an operation's research perspective the customer is asked to make a trade off at the time of product purchase to minimize current costs while taking into consideration the future costs of repair. This is usually very difficult since most customers are often unsure of a product's reliability, but they would like the peace of mind knowing that for at least the period of coverage beyond the base warranty, they will not have to incur future and often expensive repair costs. This is particularly important for the business user on a tight budget since expensive repair costs can bankrupt a business. And to further complicate the EW decision, in industries with rapid technological innovation, such as consumer electronics, customers may not know how soon they may wish to upgrade to a newer product with more features. Product lifecycles are continually shrinking and are in some businesses down to less than a year, e.g., cell phones. Thus it may not be an optimal strategy for a customer to commit to a multi-year EW in a rapidly changing product environment.
All of these issues could be substantially addressed through a monthly or quarterly EW if properly designed. A monthly warranty allows customers to choose the duration of coverage with finer granularity, and more importantly, the customer only has to commit and pay on a monthly or other short-term basis for the warranty coverage. From a customer's perspective it reduces the complexity of minimizing current costs while taking into consideration the future costs of repair. Such an EW would be purchased while the product is still new or at least still under the base warranty, but the customer could cancel it at various times during the life of the contract and may even be allowed to receive a partial refund if repairs have been nonexistent. This arrangement could be very attractive to a much broader range of customers who have never considered EWs in the past.
For a traditional service provider who sells warranties with one or more full-years of coverage, the introduction of flexible monthly EWs has its hazards since monthly contracts may cannibalize demand for the traditional long-term EWs. Therefore, flexible EWs need to be carefully designed and properly priced in order to avoid eroding profits. It is crucial to properly characterize the potential costs and economic decisions in such an environment if the service provider is to maximize profits. If a flexible EW is priced too high, most customers would not find it attractive and would not sign up for the coverage. If priced too low, the customers may like it, but the EW service provider would lose money over the life of the EW contract. Although there have been numerous studies and papers written where EWs have been modeled, there have been very few studies that properly model optimal EW strategies whether from the perspective of the customer or from the perspective of the manufacturer/service provider. And very few of these deal with flexible EW contracts or for the situation where a customer can make dynamic repair or replacement decisions in each covered or uncovered payment period. Our modeling tool, as will be seen, allows customers to make dynamic repair or replacement decisions in each period, based on the product's failure status or on other criteria. (As product prices decline as a result of competition and technology innovations, product replacement is becoming an increasingly viable alternative to costly repairs and EW coverage.)
Further limitations and disadvantages of conventional and traditional approaches will become apparent to one skilled in the art, through comparison of such devices with a representative embodiment of the present invention as set forth in the remainder of the present application with reference to the drawings.
For a better understanding of the invention as well as further features thereof, reference is made to the following description which is to be read in conjunction with the accompanying drawings wherein:
Reference will now be made in detail to a representative embodiment of the present invention shown generally in the accompanying drawings. Furthermore, in the following detailed description, numerous specific details are set forth in order to provide a thorough understanding of the present invention. However, it will be obvious to one of ordinary skill in the art that the present invention can be practiced without these specific details.
To understand the underlying methods disclosed, it is first necessary to define some basic assumptions and the notation used in the Figures and in the modeling framework. We consider a customer who has just purchased a new product, for example something like a personal computer, and who would like to maximize the expected discounted net utility derived from this product over a finite period of time defined as a time horizon of N periods. A period may represent a month, a week, a quarter of a year, or any other fixed duration of time. In each such period the customer makes certain maintenance, replacement, and coverage decisions about the product. If it is broken, should it be repaired or should it be replaced with a newer model? Should the customer buy EW coverage for it assuming such is available?
In the following description, we use the following terminology to define the key expressions and variables involved in the customer and service provider decisions.
One aspect of the invention consider a general monthly EW that offers complete coverage flexibility to the customer in terms of his ability to turn coverage on and off whenever desired. This flexibility makes the warranty more attractive to most customers than a traditional, fixed-term EW, especially for those individuals with financial constraints. In the context of this monthly warranty example, the “period” is defined to he a month. One could similarly define a quarterly warranty in which the period represents a quarter of a year.
The Customer's Strategy
The customer's economic analysis is in deciding which months to buy coverage for and when to repair or replace the product, in order to maximize the expected discounted value from the product, net of costs for repair, coverage and product replacement. The customer in this model is allowed to turn on and off coverage at any time, although in other embodiments of our invention, restrictions can be imposed on when coverage can be purchased. We formulate the customer's optimal maintenance and coverage decisions as a dynamic program. Dynamic programming is a method of breaking down large complex decision problems into a set of simpler subproblems. For example a problem that involves determining the best decisions over several time periods can be broken down into sub-problems that involve determining the decision in each individual time period, while considering the impact of the decision on the current period as well as on subsequent periods. Such is the case in our application of dynamic programming to finding a customer's optimal decisions over a time horizon, and maximum expected discounted value over that horizon. We break the problem down into subproblems, each of which involves determining decisions for a single time period. The dynamic program considers the impact of current-period decisions on current and future value to the customer.
The description of a dynamic program includes its state, which summarizes all relevant information about the system (i.e., the status of the product) as it evolves. The state may have multiple variables in its description. In the dynamic program describing customer's optimal product replacement and monthly EW purchase decisions, we let c represent a state variable denoting the known repair costs a customer faces for a failure that occurred in the previous month. Where c=0 the customer had no failure in the previous month, and c>0 indicates that a failure occurred in the previous month or some other preceding month where no action was taken. A second state variable is the product's age a as defined above. We also let the variable Z indicate whether the customer had warranty coverage for failures that may or may not have occurred in the previous month(s).
If Z=1, this indicates that the preceding month's failures were covered, and if Z=0, this indicates that they were not covered.
When the repair cost c>0, the customer must choose to either repair the product (at cost c, if the product was not covered by a warranty, i.e., uncovered, or at a co-payment cost of h(c) if the product was covered by a warranty), replace the product with a new one at price q, or stop using the product and not buy a replacement—thereafter earning zero product utility and incurring no costs. We prohibit the customer from turning on the coverage after the occurrence of a failure without first restoring the product to a functional state. If c=0, the product is in a functional state, and the customer may choose to keep it or replace it, i.e., no repair is necessary. At the beginning of each month, the customer has an option to buy coverage for the month at cost pa for a product of age a.
It is also possible to generalize the model to introduce the concept of a refund r≦pa on the monthly warranty premium that is paid to the customer if no claim is made against the warranty in the month in which coverage was purchased. An important special case is when r=0. However, allowing a more general r enables us to model a broader range of services, including a contingent service, within the same framework.
We let state S=(c, a, Z) denote the state of the product in each month, where
c=the cost of a repair for a failure (if any) that occurred in the previous month,
a=the age of the product, and
Z=the coverage status in the preceding month.
We count time backward, i.e., n is the remaining number of months to go in the horizon. And let
Vn(S)=customer's maximum expected discounted value over the next n months before making replacement decision, starting in state S=(c, a, Z). And,
Wn(a)=customer's maximum expected discounted value over the next n months after making replacement decision, starting with a functional (i.e., working) product of age a.
In the dynamic program, the customer determines his optimal decisions in a given month by considering the impact of decisions in the current month as well as the future impact of the decisions. The customer's decisions in each month are characterized by the following dynamic equations:
Keep or Replace Decision:
V
n(c, a, Z)=max{Wn(a)−cIz=0−h(c)Iz=1, Wn(a)−c+rIz=1, Wn(0)−q+rIz=1, rIz=1+αVn−1(c, a+1,0)}, for c>0 (1)
reflecting the customer's choices between making a claim for a failed product (if it is covered), repairing at his own expense, replacing the product, or doing nothing, and,
V
n(0, a, Z)=max{Wn(a)+rIz=1, Wn(0)−q+rIz=1} (2)
where Iz=k is an indicator variable equal to 0 or 1(1 if Z=k and otherwise 0). This equation reflects the customer's decision between keeping a functional product or replacing it.
Coverage Decision:
W
n(a)=ua+max{α[(1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,1)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1,1)]]−pa, α[(1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,0)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1,0)]]}, (3)
Without loss of generality, suppose the boundary conditions describing the customer's expected discounted net utility with zero periods remaining are as follows:
W
0(a)=sa.
V
0(0, a, Z)=sa+rIZ=1, and
V
0(c, a, Z)=max(sa−h(c)IZ=1−cIZ=0, rIZ=1) for c>0.
The customer's maximum expected discounted value over an N-month horizon, starting with a new product, is WN(0).
One can observe that in each of equations (1), (2) and (3), the customer makes a decision based on the current state of the system, including the product failure status, its age, and (in the case of replacement decisions) its coverage status. Different states may result in different decisions. Moreover, the replacement or coverage decision in each state and period is selected to be the one that yields the maximum expected discounted net utility, including utility earned in the current period plus the expected discounted utility from future periods resulting from these decisions. Because of the dependency of current decisions on future expected discounted utility, the value functions with n periods remaining in the horizon, Vn(S) and Wn(a), cannot he computed until the value functions Vn−1(S) and Wn−1(a) are known. Thus, the customer's value functions must be computed recursively starting from n=0. After computing Vn(S) and Wn(a) for n=0, the customer then computes the same value functions for n=1, and then n=2, etc, and is finished when he computes the value functions for n=N.
Note that there may be a very large number of possible values of the state, and as such, steps 105-108 are very computationally intensive.
We are not implying that any actual customer will exhibit such a strategy to optimize his economic decisions, particularly since the customer may not have all the various parameters available to him (such as the failure rates of a product or the likely repair costs), and since this approach is computationally intensive and therefore may be impractical to implement in one's head. But if all the parameters were known then the rational customer could make these decisions to maximize his expected discounted net utility. Thus technique 100 for determining a customer's optimal dynamic decisions is an important step to have available, since it has an impact on the profitability of the OEM/service provider as shown below. (Because this process is very computationally intensive and because the typical individual customer does not usually have all the various parameters available in making the decisions to maximize his expected discounted net utility, the service discussed below is another aspect of this invention that can provide very useful information to a customer not otherwise available.)
The preceding model is quite general in that it allows for copayments and refunds of warranty premia based on claim behavior of the customer. Important special cases of the monthly warranty which can be implemented into our computerized tool include:
Basic Monthly EW. In the most basic monthly EW, the customer is not charged copayments [h(c)=0 for all c] and is given no refund regardless of claim history (r=0).
Monthly EW with Copay. A monthly copayment EW charges the customer a fixed copayment for repairs [h(c)=h for all c] and gives no refund regardless of claim history (r=0). The copayment may be the costs to ship the item to and from the repair facility, for example.
Contingent Service. Now consider a monthly warranty for which the full monthly premium is refunded to a customer who made no claims against the warranty (r=pa). Moreover, suppose that if the customer chooses to repair a product under warranty, he is charged a copayment equal to the warranty provider's repair costs. Then the copayment is h(c)=βc for a repair that would cost the customer (c) out-of-warranty. We call such a warranty a contingent service.
Service Provider's Profits
Obviously the strategic economic behavior of customers has an impact on the profitability of the OEM/service provider. By properly modeling the service provider's profits, it is possible to consider the important question of how to design and price a monthly warranty. The notation used below to describe the service provider's profit is as follows.
VΠn(c., a, Z)=service provider's total expected discounted profit from a customer starting in state (c, a, Z) with n months to go, before the customer's replacement decision; and,
WΠn(a)=service provider's total expected discounted profit from a customer starting with a functional product of age a with n months to go, after the customer's replacement decision has been made.
The service provider's profits in each month are characterized by the following dynamic equations:
Keep or replace decision (for nonfunctional, products covered by an EW):
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=h(c)−βc+WΠn(a). (4)
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=−r+WΠn(a), (5)
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=(1−θ)q−r+WΠn(0), (6)
VΠ
n(c, a 1)=−r+αVΠn−1(c, a, 1, 0). (7)
Keep or replace decision (for nonfunctional products not covered by an EW):
V∪
n(c, a, 0)=WΠn(a) (8)
VΠ
n(c, a, 0)=(1−θ)q+WΠn(0) (9)
VΠ
n(c, a, 0)=αVΠn−1(c, a+1,0). (10)
And the keep or replace decision (for functional products) is:
VΠ
n(0, a, Z)=(1−θ)q−rIz=1+WΠn(0), (11)
VΠ
n(0, a, Z)=WΠn(a)−rIz=1, (12)
If Wn(a)≧Wn(0)−q, then the customer would prefer to continue with a product of age a (earning expected discounted utility Wn(a)) than to pay q to replace the product and continue with a new (age 0) product (earning an expected discounted utility of Wn(0)−q). Then the decision for the customer whether to purchase coverage or not purchase it in this period is as follows:
if α((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,1)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1,1)]−pa≧α((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,0)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1,0)]),
then the customer prefers to purchase EW coverage in this period, and
WΠ
n(a)=pa+α(1−fa)VΠn−1(0, a+1,1)+faECa[VΠn−1(Ca, a+1,1)]), (13)
Otherwise, the customer prefers not to purchase EW coverage, and:
WΠ
n(a)=α((1−fa)VΠn−1(0, a+1,0)+faECa[VΠn−1(Ca, a+1,0)]). (14)
The boundary conditions are:
WΠ
0(a)=0,
VΠ
0(0, a, Z)=−rIz=1, and
VΠ
0(c, a, Z)=0 for c>0.
While the provider's total expected discounted profit from a new, hardware customer over an N-period horizon is WΠN(0).
One can observe that in equations (4)-(14), the profit functions with n periods remaining in the horizon, VΠn(S) and WΠn(a), cannot be computed until the profit functions VΠn−1(S) and WΠn−1(a) are known. Thus, the provider's profit functions must be computed recursively starting from n=0. After computing VΠn(S) and WΠn(a) for n=0, the provider then computes the same value functions for n=1, then n=2, etc, and is finished when he computes the value functions for n=N.
We then proceed to step 208 in
At this point we have completed the required computations for n=1. We proceed to step 210 where we check whether n<N. If n<N, then we increment n by 1 at step 211 and go back to step 203 to perform steps 203 through 211 again for the incremented value of n. We repeat steps 203 through 211 for successive values of n until we have completed steps 203-210 for n=N. If n=N, we branch to step 212 and report the expected discounted net utility WΠN(0) which represents the provider's total expected discounted profit from the customer over the entire N-period horizon when the customer starts with a new (a=0) product.
A second important element of the monthly warranty invention is that we have specified a method to compute the provider's expected discounted profit over the horizon from the perspective of a strategic customer who is offered a monthly warranty, through the equations described above. This is another building block for the methodology to design and more importantly price profitable warranties:
Refundable EWs
It is possible to extend this methodology to a traditional EW that may or may not be refundable, i.e., provide a refund to a customer, whether in the form of a cash rebate or as a credit on future product, upon termination of the EW coverage. We assume that this EW must be purchased when the covered product is new, that is when a=0. If we let p denote the price of the EW, and d denote the coverage duration of the EW, the EW, if purchased, covers failures that occur in months with product age a=0, 1, 2, . . . , (d−1). As in the previous section, state S=(c, a Z) denotes the state of the product before the repair/replacement decision is made in a given month, where c indicates the cost of repair of a failure (if any) that occurred in the preceding month, a indicates the product age, and Z indicates the coverage status for failures that occurred in the preceding month.
To simplify the dynamic programming equations, let Z′(a) denote the coverage status for failures during a month for a product of age a that had an EW purchased when the product was new. Thus,
Z′(a)=1 for a<d and
Z′(a)=0 if a≧d.
When the customer makes a claim for failure within the warranty coverage period (i.e., a<d), the customer then makes a co-payment of h(c) which is less than what an out-of-warranty repair cost c would be. To generalize a refund from the monthly EW so as to be age-dependent: let r(a) denote the refund for an EW that is canceled when the product is age a, 0≦a≦d−1. This age dependent refund schedule allows for a pro-rated refund structure. Then
Vn(S)=the maximum expected discounted value over the next n months before making
a replacement decision, starting in state S=(c, a, Z), and
Wn(a, Z)=the maximum expected discounted value over the next n months after making a
The customer's decisions in each month are characterized by the following dynamic equations:
Keep or replace decision:
V
n(c, a, 0)=max{Wn(a, 0)−c, Wn(0, 0)−q, αVn−1(c, a+1, 0)}, c>0, a≧1 (15)
V
n(c, a, 1)=max{Wn(a, Z′(a))−h(c)+r(a)Ia=d, Wn(0,0)−q+r(a), rIa=d+αVn−1(c, a+1, Z′(a))}, for c>0, and 1≦a≦d, (16)
V
n(0, a, 0)=max{Wn(a, 0),Wn(0, 0)−q}, (17)
V
n(0, a, 1)=max{Wn(a, Z′(a))+rIa=d, Wn(0, 0)−q+r(a)}, for 1≦a≦d. (18)
Equation (15) characterizes the customer's economic decisions when the product is not functioning and when the failure occurred without warrant coverage. At that juncture the customer must decide whether to repair, replace, or do nothing with the broken product.
Equation (16) characterizes a customer's economic decisions about a non-functioning product whose failure was covered under a warranty. The customer again must decide whether to repair it (i.e., make a claim), replace it, or do nothing with the broken/nonfunctioning product.
Equation (17) characterizes the customer's economic choices for a functioning uncovered product: to keep or to replace it.
And equation (18) describes the same economic choices for a functioning covered product: to keep or to replace it.
Now we address the customer's EW coverage choices.
W
n(0, 0)=ua+max{α((1−f0)Vn−1(0, 1, 1)+f0EC0[Vn−1(C0, 1, 1)])−p, α((1−f0)Vn−1(0, 1, 0)+f0EC0[Vn−1(C0, 1, 0)])}, (19)
W
n(a, 0)=ua+α((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1, 0)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1, 0)]), a≧1 (20)
W
n(a, 1)=ua+max{α((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,1)+faECa[Vn−1(Ca, a+1, 1)]), r(a)+α((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1, 0)+faECa[Vn-1(Ca, a+1, 0)]} (21)
Equation (19) characterizes the customer's choice for purchasing or not purchasing a warranty for a new product. The second equation (20) describes the customer's expected discounted utility for a non-new, uncovered product. The customer has no decision to make in this case. He can nether purchase coverage, nor cancel coverage, since warranty coverage in one embodiment of this invention must be started when the product is new if at all. In another embodiment it is possible to permit a customer to turn EW coverage on or off, but then it is necessary to introduce an activation fee charged when coverage is reactivated. (Obviously there are additional costs incurred by the service provider to verify that the product is operational when coverage is turned back on. Note that this is discussed below.) Equation (21) reflects the customer's choices for a non-new product with coverage: whether to continue coverage or cancel it.
Without loss of generality, suppose that the boundary conditions are as follows:
W
n(a, Z)=sa+r(a)IZ=1,
V
0(0, a, Z)=sa+r(a)IZ=1 and
V
0(c, a, Z)=max(sa+r(a)IZ=1−cIZ=0, r(a)IZ=1) for c>0.
The customer's maximum expected discounted utility over an N-period horizon, starting with a new product, is WN(0,0).
An important part of the flexible or refundable warranty invention is the specification of a method to compute the customer's maximum total expected discounted net utility from a refundable warranty over the horizon, through the dynamic programming equations specified above. This is one of the building blocks for the methodology to design and price profitable warranties. Like the monthly or periodic invention, this model reflects the customer's ability to dynamically make maintenance and replacement decisions as failures occur, unlike prior art approaches. There are, however, special cases of an EW worth mentioning including:
Service Provider's Profits
The service provider's expected discounted profits under the refundable EW can be expressed in a similar manner. Using the same notation as in the case of a monthly EW:
There are four situations to consider in assessing the service provider's profit: nonfunctioning, covered products, i.e., (1≦a≦d, c>0), nonfunctioning uncovered products (c>0), functioning, covered products (1≦a≦d), and functioning uncovered products. For nonfunctioning, covered products the keep-or-replace decision is as follows.
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=h(c)−βc−r(a)Ia=d+Wn(a, Z′(a)). (22)
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=(1−θ)q−r(a)+WΠn(0), (23)
VΠ
n(c, a, 1)=−r(a)Ia=d+αVΠn−1(c, a+1, Z′(a)). (24)
For nonfunctioning, uncovered products (c>0), the keep or replace decision is as follows.
if Wn(a, 0)−c≧max{Wn(0, 0)−q, αVn−1(c, a+1, 0)}, the customer prefers to repair the product, and
VΠ
n(c, a, 0)=WΠn(a, 0) (25)
if Wn(0, 0)−q≧max{Wn(a, 0)−c, αVn−1(c, a+1, 0)}, the customer prefers to replace the product, and
VΠ
n(c, a, 0)=(1−θ)q+WΠn(0,0), (26)
if αVn−1(c, a+1,0)≧max{Wn(a, 0)−c, Wn(0,0)−q},
the customer prefers to take no action in the month in question, and
VΠ
n(c, a, 0)=αVΠn−1(c, a+1,0). (27)
For functioning, covered products (1≦a≦d), the keep or replace decision is as follows.
If Wn(a, Z′(a))+r(a)Ia=d≧Wn(0,0)−q+r(a),
the customer prefers to keep the product, and
VΠ
n(0, a, 1)=−r(a)Ia=d+WΠn(a, Z′(a)), (28)
if Wn(0,0)−q+r(a)>WΠn(a, Z′(a))+r(a)Ia=d,
the customer prefers to replace the product, and
VΠ
n(0, a, 1)=(1−θ)q−r(a)+WΠn(0, 0). (29)
Then for functioning, uncovered products:
if Wn(a, 0)≧Wn(0, 0)−q,
the customer prefers to keep the product, and
VΠ
n(0, a, 0)=WΠn(a, 0), (30)
if Wn(0,0)−q>Wn(a, 0), the customer prefers to replace the product, and
VΠ
n(0, a, 0)=(1−θ)q+WΠn(0, 0). (31)
The customer's decision to obtain warranty coverage is as follows:
for new products (i.e., where a=0),
WΠ
n(0,0)=p+α((1−f0)VΠn−1(0, 1, 1)+f0EC0[VΠn−1(C0, 1, 1)]). (32)
Otherwise, the customer prefers not to purchase coverage, and
WΠ
n(0,0)=((1−f0)VΠn−1(0, 1, 0)+f0EC0[VΠn−1(C0, 1, 0)]). (33)
For products that are not covered by a warranty and that are not new (i.e., where a≧1); the customer has no decision to make since:
WΠ
n(a, 0)=α((1−fa)VΠn−1(0, a+1,0)+faECa[VΠn−1(Ca, a+1,0)]). (34)
But for products covered by a warranty (where 1≦a≦(d−1)):
WΠ
n(a, 1)=α((1−fa)VΠn−1(0, a+1,1)+faECa[VΠn−1(Ca, a+1,1)]). (35)
Otherwise, the customer prefers to cancel the warranty coverage, and
WΠ
n(a, 1)=−r(a)+α((1−fa)VΠn−1(0, a+1,0)+faECa[VΠn−1(Ca, a+1,0)]). (36)
The service provider's total expected discounted profit from a new hardware customer over an N-period horizon is WΠN(0, 0). This represents the maximum total expected discounted utility over the entire horizon, starting with a new product (assuming that optimal decisions are followed throughout the horizon.
Another important element of the refundable warranty invention is a method to compute the provider's expected discounted profit over the horizon from a strategic customer who is offered a refundable warranty, through the equations described above.
There are several ways in which the preceding models for monthly and refundable EW can be further generalized. Each of these generalizations is potentially valuable from a commercial perspective, and so we believe they are all important aspects of the invention.
Restrictions on monthly warranty coverage: The preceding discussion of the monthly EW allowed customers to turn coverage on and off whenever they liked. One could easily introduce restrictions on when coverage could be purchased. For example, we could impose a requirement that coverage must be started in the first month (or few months) of the product life. We could also limit the product age at which one could purchase coverage for a product to limit the provider's exposure to high failure costs for very old products. These ideas can be implemented as restrictions, or instead implemented monetarily through payments of activation fees or high monthly premia for products beyond some predetermined age.
Competition for hardware replacements: Consider the case in which the service provider is also a manufacturer of the product in question. When a customer decides to replace the hardware product, he chooses to replace with hardware from the same manufacturer with probability “ρ.” If he chooses a different hardware brand, then the manufacturer will lose the future profits from this customer. (We assume there are one or more competing hardware providers in the marketplace.) The customer can choose any of these other hardware providers and can expect the same future costs as would be incurred if the original provider were selected.
Competition for out-of-warranty repair services: each time a customer chooses to repair a product out of warranty, we assume that the customer chooses the original manufacturer to provide this service with probability “ω” and an alternative service provider having the same repair prices with probability (1−ω).
Restricted-use refunds: rather than paying cash refunds, a manufacturer/provider may choose to pay refunds in the form of a credit toward the purchase of new hardware from the same provider. In this case, the provider only needs to pay the refund if the customer buys a replacement product from the same provider. The customer places less value on the refundability of the EW when the refund is issued as a hardware credit, because the refund only materializes with probability ρ. However, credit-type refunds may increase his repurchase probability for this brand as compared to cash refunds. These effects can be captured in the model.
Claim-dependent refunds on refundable EW. We can also generalize the refundable EW to make the refund schedule dependent on the number of claims made against the warranty. This requires a state space expansion to include one additional state variable, the number of claims made so far against the warranty. Note that such state space expansion will slow down the solution of the customer dynamic programming and computation of provider profits. This generalization allows us to model residual value EWs and in particular, risk-free EWs, i.e., where the entire price of the EW is refunded to customers who have no claims during the coverage period.
Activation fees for monthly EW: a hardware provider may want to charge an activation fee for a monthly EW that is dependent upon the age of the product when the warranty is first purchased after one or more months without coverage. An activation fee can cover the costs of verifying that the product is functioning when coverage begins. Making the activation fee age-dependent can help to remove the adverse selection problem arising from customers wishing to insure only old, failure-prone products. Adding this feature to the EW model requires the addition of a state variable indicating whether the product was under warranty in the previous period.
Information asymmetry in product reliability and repair cost distribution: the customer may not know the true failure probabilities or failure cost distribution. A customer may base maintenance, replacement and coverage decisions on an incorrect belief about these distributions, whereas the provider profits are based on accurate product reliability information.
Breakdown of costs and profits: when computing the provider's expected discounted profits, one could easily determine how these profits decompose into profits from hardware replacements, out-of-warranty repair, and EW sales. This decomposition can be instructive because the results illustrate, in aggregate, the choices customers are making when offered the service, without having to examine the choices made for every element of the state space. Similarly, when computing expected discounted customer utility, one can also compute the customer's expected discounted costs from replacements, services and out-of-warranty repairs.
To facilitate a better understanding of our methodology of evaluating flexible EWs, consider the following typical application of one aspect of an embodiment of our invention. The numerical data used in the example below was chosen to be representative of an inexpensive personal computing product, such as a netbook, for which a monthly EW may be more appealing than a traditional, fixed-term EW.
The horizon length is T=24 months.
We assume a linear increase in failure probabilities over a product's life as depicted in the graph shown in
Customers are assumed to be heterogeneous in their utility schedule. In this example there are five customer classes. Customer class j has utility schedule given by u(a,j)=100e−0.02ja. Thus each customer starts with the same utility of $100 in the first month, but the utility increasingly decays over time for the higher customer class indices. The utility schedules for each customer type are shown in
Product replacement cost is q=$500.
It is also assumed that there is no salvage value for the product at the end of the horizon. Thus, sa=0 for all a.
Future cash flow is not discounted, so the discount factor is α=1.
When a product breaks, the customer's out-of-warranty repair cost is a constant c=$100. (This is an oversimplification of reality, but it helps to make the example easier to follow. In general the repair costs for products of the same model or type would vary depending on the type of failure that had occurred. They would be monitored and tracked to come up with a distribution of repair costs at each age.)
The cost to the provider to repair a product is β=50% of the out-of-warranty . repair cost for the same repair. Thus, the provider earns (1−β)=50% margin on out-of-warranty repairs, equal to $50 for each repair in this hypothetical situation.
When a customer repairs a product out-of-warranty, he goes to the OEM for the repairs ω=30% of the time.
In the particular hypothetical example chosen we assume a monthly EW with no refund or copayment. The monthly premium is assumed to be a constant pm=$2.50. For each customer class, the dynamic difference equations can be simplified as follows. The keep or replace decision (where c>0, a≧1) can be characterized as:
V
n(c, a, 0)=max{Wn(a)−c, Wn(0)−q, Vn−1(c, a+1,0)}, (37)
V
n(c, a, 1)=Vn(0, a, Z)=max{Wn(a), Wn(0)−q}, where Z=0, 1. (38)
Equation 37 represents the situation where the customer faces a nonfunctioning product whose failure in the prior month was not covered by a warranty. Thus the customer must choose between repairing the product at his own expense c and then continuing with a product of age a (thus obtaining an expected discounted net utility of Wn(a) from that point on), replacing it at cost q and continuing with a new product (obtaining Wn(0) expected discounted net utility from that point on), or take no action in this period and continuing in the following period with a nonfunctioning product of age a+1 and earning only Vn−1(c, a+1, 0) expected discounted net utility from that point on.
Equation 38 represents three cases in which the customer faces identical choices. And the expression Vn(c, a, 1) corresponds to a customer who has a nonfunctioning product for which the preceding month's failure was covered under warranty. Therefore, in this hypothetical, the customer can have the product repaired at no cost to him. The expression Vn(0, a, Z) represents a customer whose PC is functioning, and so his coverage state of Z in the preceding period does not affect his decisions at this stage. In any of these cases the customer must choose between keeping the product and then continuing with a product of age a (thus obtaining an expected discounted net utility of Wn(a) from that point on), or choosing to replace the product at a cost q and continuing with a new product (obtaining Wn(0) expected discounted net utility from that point on).
The customer's coverage decision can be expressed as follows.
W
n(a)=ua+max{Vn−1(0, a+1,1)−pm, ((1−fa)Vn−1(0, a+1,0)+faVn−1(c, a+1,0))}. (39)
Equation 39 represents a customer's coverage decision when there is a functioning product of age a with n periods remaining after making maintenance or replacement decisions in this period. The customer earns a utility ua from the product in this period and has two choices to make regarding warranty coverage.
The boundary conditions are:
W
0(a)=0,
V
0(0, a, Z)=0 and
V
0(c, a, Z)=0.
According to the dynamic difference equations (37)-(39) above, since the boundary conditions are known, it is possible to compute the customer's expected discounted value Vn over the next n months before making a replacement decision looking backward from n=1 and find the optimal policy for each state. For purposes of this example we consider a customer class 2. For instance, when the time to go is n=12, we obtain the values for V12 in the Table shown in
To determine the customer's optimal economic decisions when n=13, i.e., when there are 13 periods remaining in the horizon, consider the decisions that the customer must make if the product age is a=5 as an example. According to equation 39 the customer decides between purchasing coverage for the month at a cost of pm=$2.50 and then incurring an expected discounted net utility of V12(0, 6, 1)=$702.63 (as shown in the Table in
or a total of $700.03 from that point onward. And since $700.03>$700.13 the customer preference is to purchase coverage (albeit a very small preference), and
W
13(5)=u5+$700.13=$81.87+$700.13=$782.
This is shown in the table of
Before making the repair-replace decision for n=13 months at an age a=5, it is necessary to compute W13(0), which is the expected discounted net utility if the customer replaces the product in n=13 months, which can be obtained by considering the coverage decision (Eqn. 39) for a new product (i.e., a=0) in n=13 months. If the customer purchases coverage for a new product in n =13, the total expected discounted net utility is
u0−pm+V12(0, 1, 1)=$100−$2.50+$870.14=$967.64. (See second column, second row of
u
0(1−f0)V12(0, 1, 0)+f0V12(c, 1, 0)=$100+(1−0.02)($870.14)+0.02($770.14)=$968.14.
(See second column, third row of
And since $968.14>$967.64, the customer prefers slightly not to purchase coverage and W13(0)=$968.14. This is reflected in the table shown in
The repair-replace decision: for n=13 and a=5, where there are several situations to consider. If the product is not functioning and its most recent failure was not under warranty, then the customer is in state (c, 5, 0). If the product is functioning, then the customer is in state (0, 5, 0) or (0, 5, 1). If the product is nonfunctioning, but its failure was covered under a warranty, then the customer is in state (c, 5, 1).
From the customer's perspective, these four cases can effectively be grouped into two states.
The preceding example illustrates how to compute the maximum expected discounted values W13 and V12, exemplifying how the difference equations are computed backwards from n=1. The two tables shown in
The Manufacturer's or Service Provider's Expected Discounted Profit
If we consider the same example as above, we can obtain the service provider's expected discounted profits when there are n=12 periods remaining, VΠ12, in the table shown in
First consider the coverage decisions. The customer decides to buy coverage for a functioning product when n=13 and a=5, since
V
12(0, 6, 1)−pm>[(1−fa)V12(0, 6, 0)+faV12(c, 6, 0)].
As a result of this choice; from equation (13) above, we know that:
So now consider the implications to the manufacturer/provider of the customer's maintenance and replacement decision in each possible state for n=13 and a=5.
VΠ
13(c, 5, 0)=WΠ13(5)=$8.45. (43)
W
13(5)≧max(W13(0)−q, V12(c, 6, 0)).
VΠ
13(c, 5, 1)=−βc+WΠ13(5)=−(0.5)($100)+$8.45 or $41.55. (45)
W
13(5)>W13(0)−q.
VΠ
13(0, 5, 0)=VΠ13(0, 5, 1)=WΠ13(5)=$8.45. (46)
This is how the service provider determines the expected discounted profits in each state with n=13 periods (months) remaining and with a product of age a=5.
Designing and Pricing Extended Warranties
The disclosure above characterizes customer utility and provider profits for both monthly and refundable-type of EWs. However, how does one optimally design an EW contract or menu of EW contracts to maximize expected discounted profits? In considering the provider's design and pricing problem, it is best to consider competition, customer heterogeneity, and customer demand for services. There could be a plurality of competing service providers in the market. And in general there is a heterogeneous population of customers, varying in product utility schedules, failure probabilities, repair cost distribution, risk attitudes, price sensitivity, or other attributes. For purposes of one embodiment of this invention, we assume there is a known distribution of customer attribute profiles over the population. Furthermore when presented with multiple service options, customers may choose the services that offer the lowest expected discounted cost or highest expected discounted net utility, or they may be influenced by latent preferences or random errors in measurement that add randomness to their choice. To capture the more general case we formulate a customer demand using a multinomial logit (MNL) model which is a type of customer choice model. When price sensitivity is sufficiently large this model results in customers choosing the maximum utility option. At the other extreme, when price sensitivity is zero, customers are equally likely to choose any of the options, regardless of utility.
Suppose that the customer population consists of set of I different types of customers. Then let g(i) be the percentage of the customer population that is of type i, where i=1, . . . , I and Σi=1Ig(i)=1. We can thus think of g(i) as representing the probability that a randomly selected customer is of type i.
Suppose also that there is a set of services S available in the marketplace. For a given service {s ∈ S}, let (ps) be a vector representing the design parameters of the service s, including the warranty price per period for each product age, any copayment, its refund schedule, etc. Then let Usi(ps) be the maximum expected discounted net utility over an N-period horizon for a customer of type i who can choose between corresponding expected discounted profits for the provider of service s, pay-as-you-go service, and product replacement. Then let Zsi(ps) be the corresponding expected discounted profits for the provider of service s, including profits from service, replacements and pay-as-you-go repairs from a customer of type i, given design vector (ps) for the service. Note that the service profits to the provider may be zero if the customer opts not to buy the service with attributes (ps). The quantities Usi(ps) and Zsi(ps) can be computed in accordance with the dynamic equations (1-14) above when s represents a monthly EW, and (15-36) in the case that s represents a refundable EW above. For example ifs is a monthly EW as described earlier, then
U
s
i(ps)=WN(0) and Zsi(ps)=WΠN(0)
If instead s is a refundable EW as also described above, then
U
s
i(ps)=WN(0,0) and Zsi(ps)=WΠN(0,0).
(The dependence of WN and WΠN on i and ps is implicit.)
We assume that the customer demand for services is driven by a multinomial logit model. In particular a customer of type i who is faced with the choice among services {s ∈ S} will choose service s with a probability equal to:
where γi is a choice sensitivity parameter for customers of type i and p=(pi, . . . , ps) is a matrix containing the design parameters for all services available on the market. In this embodiment we assume that if a customer selects a service s at the beginning of the horizon, then that customer will buy the same service thereafter.
From the perspective of a service provider who offers a subset of those services, T ⊂ S, he wants to maximize expected discounted profits from these services given the design parameters of competitor's services in S/T. The provider's problem is that of finding design parameters {pt, t ∈ T} to maximize his total expected discounted profits of:
The provider's problem of finding design parameters {pt, t ∈ T} is a nonlinear optimization problem. One could implement any of several well-known optimization procedures, such as line search, to find the optimal parameters.
Referring to
While aspects of the present invention have been described with reference to certain embodiments, it will be understood by those skilled in the art that various changes may be made and equivalents may be substituted without departing from the scope of the representative embodiments of the present invention. In addition, many modifications may be made to adapt a particular situation to the teachings of a representative embodiment of the present invention without departing from its scope. Therefore, it is intended that embodiments of the present invention not be limited to the particular embodiments disclosed herein, but that representative embodiments of the present invention include all embodiments falling within the scope of the appended claims.
This application is related to a nonprovisional application Ser. No. ______, filed on the same day as this application and entitled, “Flexible Extended Product Warranties.”