Integrative method for modeling multiple asset classes

Information

  • Patent Application
  • 20030110016
  • Publication Number
    20030110016
  • Date Filed
    June 29, 2001
    23 years ago
  • Date Published
    June 12, 2003
    21 years ago
Abstract
The invention provides a method and apparatus for combining two or more risk models to create a risk model with wider scope than its constituent parts. The method insures that the newly formed risk model is consistent with the component models from which it is formed.
Description


BACKGROUND OF THE INVENTION

[0001] 1. Technical Field


[0002] The invention relates to risk analysis. More particularly, the invention relates to an integrative method for modeling assets from many different asset classes. It is illustrated by application to the world equity market, when each country or regional equity market may be treated as an asset class.


[0003] 2. Description of the Prior Art


[0004] All my fortunes are at sea.


[0005] My ventures are not in one bottom trusted, nor, to one place; nor is my whole estate upon the fortune of this present year.


[0006] William Shakespeare, The Merchant of Venice (1598)


[0007] Shakespeare reminds us that the perils of investment have been with us always. Likewise, the insight that these risks can be reduced through diversification is ancient. A very recent idea, however, is that the risks can be measured and the degree of diversification can be optimized. This new insight rests on a technological advance—the risk model—which itself rests on the technological revolution produced by the computer and, more specifically, by the silicon chip.


[0008] Within the world of risk modeling there has, until recently, been a need to compromise on objectives. As long as one's focus was confined to securities within a single market, U.S. equities say, detailed analyses have been possible. When one's perspective broadens to consider equities from around the world, currencies and, however, the depth of analysis has necessarily contracted. Fundamentally this compromise between depth and breadth has been necessitated by the limitations of computing technology. In the last few years, however, these limitations have been much reduced.


[0009] It would be desirable to harness the recent increase in computing power to achieve an analysis of global asset risk which is both broad and deep.


[0010] Fundamental Concepts


[0011] The Covariance Matrix


[0012] A standard approach to characterizing financial risk is to measure the variance of the return series. Let ri(t) be the return to asset i in period t and define the asset-to-asset covariance matrix Ω by


Ωij(t)=cov(ri(t),rj(t))


[0013] where cov( ) is the covariance operator. Suppose h is the vector whose component hi gives the fraction of wealth invested in asset i by a particular portfolio. Then the variance of the portfolio return is given by


htΩh


[0014] More generally if h1 and h2 are vectors defining distinct portfolios, then the covariance of the returns to those portfolios is given by


h1tΩh2


[0015] This reduces the risk analysis of a portfolio to the problem of determining a good estimate {circumflex over (Ω)} of the asset-by-asset covariance matrix Ω.


[0016] In the last 25 years, there has been rapid growth in types of assets, such as options, where the variance may not be an adequate description of risk. In these cases, there is a set of underlying variables, such as underlying asset prices, whose riskiness is captured by their variances. Then


[0017] Ω is the covariance matrix of the underlying variables, such as underlying asset prices. For expositional simplicity, and because the variance does provide a first measure of risk, we will use portfolio covariance as a risk measure and use Ω to devote the asset level covariance matrix. The simplest estimator {circumflex over (Ω)} is the historical covariance matrix


Ωijhist(t)=cov({ri(u)rj(u)}u=t,1)


[0018] An important practical point is that the number of periods t entering into this estimate is constrained by economic realities. Let T denote the total length of time over which returns are observed and let Δ denote the observation interval. Then t=T/Δ. In general T is limited by two circumstances. First, assets have finite lives. Second, the economy itself is evolving and this evolution limits the relevance of data from the distant past. It is desirable, though not essential, for T to be at least five years. For the risk horizons of interest in a portfolio management context, e.g. from one quarter to a few years, a rule of thumb is that the observation interval Δ is best set at a one month horizon. Taking T at five years and Δ at one month results in the number of periods t being 60. The choice of 60 is not a hard number, but it represents a reasonable and necessary compromise.


[0019] The statistical properties of the estimator {circumflex over (Ω)} depend crucially on two parameters: the number of periods t in the estimate and the number of assets, a N covered by the estimate. If N>t then we may find portfolios h such that




h


t


{circumflex over (Ω)}h=
0



[0020] over the sample period. Such portfolios appear to be risk free, but in fact are not. Technically this condition is expressed by saying that {circumflex over (Ω)} fails to be positive definite. If a covariance matrix which is not positive definite is used for portfolio construction there will be a strong tendency to buy into the apparently risk free portfolios. The result is a severely biased risk estimate, with realized risks proving significantly higher than forecast risks. For this reason a positive definite covariance matrix is a basic requirement, and thus one requires t>N. Econometric considerations limit t to approximately 60, while practical applications may require N on the order of 1000. Thus, the historical asset-by-asset covariance matrix is of only limited practical utility.


[0021] The Factor Model


[0022] The limitations of the historical covariance matrix motivate the search for a more robust estimator of the asset covariances. The standard solution is to invoke a factor model. A factor model is a linear model for asset returns such that
1ri(t)=j=imXij(t)fj(t)+εi(t)


[0023] where Xij(t) is termed the exposure of asset i to factor j, fj(t) is termed the return to factor j and εj(t) is termed the specific return to asset i. The returns need not be linear in the factors, as in the case of options. Our interest is in developing a covariance matrix for factors across many asset classes and the linearity assumption does not impact the interest in any manner: Non-linear instrument may by valued directly given factor realization. For portfolio risk analysis, the linear approach is a widely-used first order approximation which greatly speeds up computations. It is further assumed that the factors fj capture all common sources of return between assets, or equivalently that




cov
(fj(t),εi(t))=0



[0024] for all factors fj(t) and specific returns εj(t) and that




cov
i(t),εk(t))=0



[0025] for distinct assets i and k. In this case with a bit of algebraic manipulation one can show


Ω=XFXt


[0026] where




F


ij
(t)=cov(fi(t),fj(t))



[0027] and
2Δij(t)=cov(εi(t),εj(t))={var(εi)ifi=j0otherwise


[0028] F is the common factor covariance matrix, and Δ is the (diagonal) matrix of specific risk. We estimate the quantities F and Δ historically.


[0029] The statistical properties of this model may be quickly summarized, based on our analysis of the sample covariance matrix. Since all assets have some specific risk, Δ>0, this insures that


{circumflex over (Ω)}fact=X{circumflex over (F)}histXthist


[0030] will be positive definite. The accuracy of the common factor risk forecasts {circumflex over (F)}hist depend on t in the average case and on the quality ratio t/m in the worst case, where m is the number of factors.


[0031] Another source of error in the factor model derives from error in the factor structure, for instance due to omission of an important factor. This source of error can be controlled for empirically. For instance, the importance of the smallest included factor gives an estimate of the likely importance of the largest missing factor, if a systematic process for constructing the factor model has been followed.


[0032] Factor Modeling Techniques


[0033] There are two basic approaches for generating factor models, which are termed the exploratory and confirmatory approaches, respectively. The exploratory approach assumes that the returns are generated by a factor model but that nothing is known about the factor model




r=Xf+ε




[0034] Various statistical techniques can then be applied to simultaneously estimate Xi and f(t) from the data ri(t). In this method X captures all the cross-sectional variation in i and f(t) captures all the temporal variation. Even so, however, X and f(t) are not uniquely defined, but rather are determined only up to a rotation of the exposures. Thus, the factors extracted by this technique are not directly interpretable. Interpretability of factors is an important consideration if a risk model is to be used for active portfolio management. In active management risks are deliberately taken in the effort to earn compensatory return. Thus, judgments must be formed as to whether or not one is willing to take on risk along a particular dimension. If the dimension is a statistical construct without an economic interpretation, there is little basis from which to form such judgments. It is usual in exploratory factor analysis to apply a rotation to the extracted factors in the hopes of arriving at an interpretation of the factors. The value of this interpretation, however, relies entirely on the analyst's judgment.


[0035] The confirmatory factor approach assumes that a priori information is available about the factor structure. In the returns based approach one assumes that the factor returns fj(t) are known. Then the exposures Xij(t) are found by regressing the asset returns on the factor returns. For instance, the market model assumes a single factor return, namely the market return m(t) in excess of the risk free rate r0(t) and it determines an asset exposure, the historical beta βhist by regressing asset returns in excess of the risk free rate on the market excess return




r


i
(t)−ro(t)=αiihist[m(t)−r0]+εi(t)



[0036] A limitation of the returns based approach is that the estimated factor exposures may not be very interpretable. A variant, known as


[0037] style analysis, attempts to correct this defect by carrying out a least squares estimation in which the exposures are restricted to lie in an a priori reasonable range. For instance, restricting the exposures to lie between 0 and 1 and to sum to 1 allows them to be interpreted as weights which describe how the factor returns are mixed together to best approximate the asset return. Note that if the data do not conform to the imposed restrictions then in general the condition.




cov
(fi(t),εj(t))=0



[0038] will fail to hold, so style analysis cannot simultaneously guarantee interpretable exposures and a consistent factor structure.


[0039] In contrast to the returns based analysis, the exposure based approach to confirmatory factor analysis assumes that the exposure matrix X is known a priori. The factor returns f(t) are then estimated by regressing the asset returns on the exposures. The exposure approach differs from other factor modeling methods in that


[0040] 1) the interpretive structure is unambiguous; and


[0041] 2) the exposure matrix can more readily vary dynamically through time.


[0042] However one generates a factor structure, one is faced with the problem of assessing its adequacy. For exploratory techniques one is guaranteed to find a structure which meets the basic assumption (1) and (2) of the factor model over the time period in which the model is estimated. The essential assessment then is whether the factor exposures estimated in this way remain stable in subsequent time periods. For returns based confirmatory factor analysis, stability of the factor exposures is again the basic criteria of success. For confirmatory analysis, by contrast, the technique only guarantees that property (1) will hold. Thus, a test of the model is verifying how well property (2) holds—i.e. are the specific returns of distinct assets uncorrelated within measurement error? It is an advantage of the confirmatory methodology that this check of the model's adequacy may be made on the estimation data itself. By contrast, the exploratory method requires data subsequent to the estimation data to arrive before the internal consistency of the model can be assessed.


[0043] Cross Asset Class and Single Asset Class Modeling


[0044] When analyzing assets in a single asset class, the most accurate risk predictions are obtained by identifying the factors appropriate to that asset class and estimating a corresponding factor model. The number of factors and length of factor realization history is almost certain to be different among the various classes. In addition, the precision of the modeling is likely to vary by asset class as is the richness of the factor structure. Each asset class is likely to have different accessibility of individual asset data so that varying levels of granularity imply that certain items of information may be available within one class but not available within another.


[0045] Confirmatory factor analysis for equities in a single country reveals that equity returns are driven by industry and style related factors. Industry related factors are self-explanatory: each firm functions within a single industry or across multiple industries, and the exposure of a firm to different industries may be computed by using a combination of sales, assets, and income from the different industries. Style related factors are based on firm fundamentals, such as size, growth, or relative trading activity, and exposure to style based factors are computed using fundamental accounting information, e.g assets, or marketing information, e.g. capitalization, trading volume. The prevalence of different industries, the availability of fundamental and market data, and the local behavior of the market then determine the final factor structure that is used for equities in a single country.


[0046] For fixed income securities, the set of factors are default free (sovereign) or high grade (swap) interest rates and spreads for lower grade instruments. The first set of factors is generally described by a set of zero coupon yields, or by the first three principle components of the set of zero coupon yields. Depending on the availability of data, the spread factors can be divided into sector and rating related spreads. In the U.S., for example, it is possible to get a fairly rich set of spread factors because of a long history of data, whereas such a history may not be available for other markets.


[0047] When integrating across many assets classes, it has in the past been difficult to work with the factors from the single asset class models, particularly for equities. The problem, discussed in detail below, is simply that there are too many factors, differing factor histories, and different types of statistical analyses that may be applied to each asset class. The natural simplification, which eliminates the need for aggregating different types of model, is to impose a common factor model structure across all asset classes. For example, one could impose a single factor model so that the aggregation process requires only the estimation of the correlation between the various factors, while at the individual asset level one only has to estimate asset exposures and residual risk. As described below in detail, this has been past practice when modeling global equities. This greatly simplifies the aggregation task but either leaves the portfolio manager with an inferior model or yields inconsistent results between the various levels within the firm hierarchy, neither of which result is actually necessary, or desirable.


[0048] To motivate our solution to the cross-asset class problem, we next illustrate the natural tension that arises between cross and within asset class risk analysis by focusing our attention on the details of modeling of global and single country equities. We then show how the invention solves the tension by providing an approach that integrates single asset class models into an aggregate asset class model. Again, this resolution is illustrated by a detailed application to the global equity market.


[0049] Prior BARRA Research


[0050] The existing approach to global equity factor modeling is closely based on the Grinold, Rudd, and Stefek model of 1989. In this approach, local market residual returns




{tilde over (r)}


i
(t)=ri(t)−rfi(t)−βi(t)mi(t)



[0051] are calculated, where


[0052] ri(t) is the return to asset i in local currency


[0053] rfi(t) is the risk free rate for the local currency of asset i


[0054] βi(t) is the beta from a five-year CAPM regression


[0055] mi(t) is the local capitalization weighted equity index return


[0056] The market residual returns are then fit to an exposure based factor model of the form
3r~t(t)=j=1NiXij1(t)fj1(t)+k=14Xik2(t)fk2+εi(t)


[0057] Here the Xij1 (t) are Ni industry exposures where for every asset i there is a unique j such that




X


ij


1
(t)=1 and for all k≠jXik1(t)=0



[0058] The quantities fj1(t) are interpreted as returns to globally defined industries. In addition, Barra's global equity model contains a set of style factors. These are embodied in Xik2(t), which are four statistical characterizations of asset i, termed SIZE, SUCCESS, VALUE and VARIABILITY IN MARKETS. These measures are based on asset characteristics normalized against the local market. The estimation of the Barra model is carried out over approximately 2000 assets, drawn from some 25 developed markets. The exact composition of the estimation universe varies through time. The commercial version of this model is known as the Global Equity Model. It exists in two different versions distinguished by slightly different industry classification schemes and estimation universes.


[0059] Since the original formulation of the Global Equity Model we have learned much about global equities:


[0060] 1) The power of exposure based factor analysis has been confirmed. Exploratory factor analysis and returns based analysis have generally confirmed findings first achieved with the Global Equity Model without generating fundamentally new insights themselves (Drummen and Zimmerman 1992, Heston and Rouwenhorst 1995). At the same time the limitations of returns based analysis have been convincingly documented (Hui 1996).


[0061] 2) All studies have found country factors to be important. However, the most recent studies find country factors to be of declining importance in Europe (Becker, Connor and Curds 1996, Freimann 1998, Connor and Herbert 1998). In discussions about the relative importance of country and global industry factors it is accordingly useful to distinguish the European situation from the rest of the world.


[0062] 3) The Global Equity Model found global industries to be important explanatory concepts. However, other studies suggest that this factor structure may be partially an analyst construct rather than an organic feature of asset returns. From a principal component analysis only the energy sector emerges as a clearly global industry (Hui 1995). Regional and country industries are found to carry substantially more explanatory power than global industries (Stefek 1991, Becker, Connor and Curds 1996). Just within Europe, continental and UK industries are found to be separate concepts (Connor and Herbert 1998).


[0063] 4) The importance of different factors fluctuates through time (Rouwenhorst 1999). Recently industry and size factors have been of considerable importance (Chandrashekaran, Hui and Rudd 1999; Cavaglia, Brightman and Aleed 2000; Bach, Garbe and Weiss 2000).


[0064] 5) A number of studies have emphasized that global equities exhibit considerable inhomogeneities. Simple differences in available data handicap a number of studies, e.g. Chaumeton and Coldiron 1999, Chandrashekaran, Hui and Rudd 1999. Specific risks are best understood in a local context (Grinold and Drach 1992). Local markets exhibit distinct behaviors of market risk (Hui 1997). Pricing appears to be local (Hui 1994). Regional concepts appear to be valid in some but not all parts of the world (Hui 1996). Local market factor structures differ (Hui 1997). Attempts to define a subuniverse of truly global companies appear problematic (Chaumeton and Coldiron 1999, Chandrashekaran, Hui and Rudd 1999). The UK appears to be only partially integrated into Europe (Connors and Herbert 1998).


[0065] 6) Risk indices are found to have high marginal explanatory power per factor (Hui 1995). However they have been entirely ignored or relatively underutilized in most studies. Compared to single country factor models, fundamental, i.e. accounting, data are underutilized in the global setting. The principal difficulty is variations in disclosure and accounting standards around the globe.


[0066] Synthesizing all of this information we are led to a new vision of global equities. Whereas the Global Equity Model saw global equities as a homogeneous group caught in a simple factor structure, we now see each local market as the homogeneous grouping with different markets linked together into a global matrix by various regional and global effects. The natural realization of this vision is to fit a factor model to each local market. The local models can be customized to each market to capture its special features and to best exploit the available data. The local analysis must then somehow be integrated into a global analysis. The work of Hui has been pointing in this direction since 1995. How to achieve the integration of local models has, however, been an elusive point. It would be advantageous to resolve this difficulty.



SUMMARY OF THE INVENTION

[0067] The invention provides a method and apparatus for combining two or more risk models to create a risk model with wider scope than its constituent parts.


[0068] The method insures that the combined risk model is consistent with the component models from which it is formed.


[0069] Starting with:


[0070] 1. Let C1 denote the class of algorithms for constructing estimates of covariance matrices from time histories of data.


[0071] 2. Let C2 denote the class of asset classes.


[0072] 3. For x in C2 let C3(x) denote the class of multi-factor risk models for x. For y in C3(x) denote its parts as follows:


[0073] Factor exposures X(y,t); at time t


[0074] Factor returns f(y,t); at time t


[0075] Specific covariance matrix D(y,t) at time t.


[0076] Factor covariance matrix F(y,t) at time t.


[0077] The following components are given:


[0078] 1. Two or more asset classes x1, . . . , xn. Let x denote the asset class which is the union of these given asset classes.


[0079] 2. For each asset class xi a risk model yi in C3(xi) is given.


[0080] 3. Let Y(t) be such that the decomposition
4(f(y1,t)f(y2,t)f(yN,t))f(t)=(Y1(t)Y2(t)YN(t))Y(t)g(t)+(φ1(t)φ2(t)φ3(t))φ(t)


[0081] which results in residuals φ(t) such that correlation (φ,φj) is nearly zero if i≠j.


[0082] Construct a risk model for x as follows:


[0083] 1. Form X(t)=diag(X(y1,t), . . . , X(yn,t)) (some detail suppressed here, see below for more details).


[0084] 2. Form D(t)=diag(D(y1,t), . . . , D(yn,t)).


[0085] 3. Apply a method from C1 to estimate a covariance matrix G(t) from the history g(t)s.


[0086] 4. Apply a possibly different method from C1 to estimate a covariance matrix Φ(t) from the history φ(t)s.


[0087] 5. Then X(t)[Y(t)G(t)Y(t)t+Φ(t)]X(t)t+D(t) is a risk model for x.


[0088] Insure the risk model in Step 5 above is consistent with each component, asset class risk model as follows:


[0089] 1. Let F1(t) be the block diagonal matrix obtained from Y(t)G(t)Y(t)′+Φ(t) by setting all elements to zero except those of the blocks corresponding to each asset class. Each block represents the covariance among the factors explaining risk for a particular asset class.


[0090] 2. Let be F2(t) the block diagonal matrix whose diagonal blocks contain the asset class factor covariance matrices, F(y1,t) in the same order as they appear in F1(t); the off-block diagonal elements are zero.


[0091] 3. Given a real symmetric positive semi-definite matrix M, let M1/2 denote a square root of M so that M1/2 (M1/2)=M. There may be several choices for M1/2. Let M−1/2 denote the inverse of M1/2, or in the event that the inverse does not exist, let M−1/2 be the pseudoinverse of M1/2.


[0092] Then X(t)(F21/2F11/2(Y(t)G(t)Y(t)′+Φ(t)(F21/2F11/2)′)X(t)′ is a risk model that is consistent with the component asset class models.







BRIEF DESCRIPTION OF THE DRAWINGS

[0093]
FIG. 1 is a graph which shows a monthly model R2;


[0094]
FIG. 2 is a graph which shows a regression model R2 versus absolute world return;


[0095]
FIG. 3 is a graph which shows cross-country correlation of purely local returns;


[0096]
FIG. 4 is a graph which shows world return history;


[0097]
FIG. 5 is a graph which shows developed world return history;


[0098]
FIG. 6 is a graph which shows emerging world return history;


[0099]
FIG. 7 is a graph which shows financial industries return history;


[0100]
FIG. 8 is a graph which shows extractive industries return history;


[0101]
FIG. 9 is a graph which shows risk index return histories;


[0102]
FIG. 10 is a graph which shows technology industry return histories; and


[0103]
FIG. 11 is a graph which shows doom & gloom return history.







DETAILED DESCRIPTION OF THE INVENTION

[0104] Construction of a Global Analysis


[0105] Combination of Models


[0106] One goal of the invention is to integrate factor models of local markets into a global analysis. For notational simplicity let us first focus on the problem of integrating just two models. Specifically, let (X1, F1, Δ1) and (X2, F2, Δ2) be two different factor models. In other words, if ri is a vector of returns from market i then




r


i
(t)=Xi(t)fi(t)+εi(t)



[0107] where




cov
(fi(t),fi(t))=Fi(t)



[0108] and




cov
i(t),εi(t))=Δi(t)



[0109] We may form new entities
5r(t)=(r1(t)r2(t))X(t)=(X1(t)00X2(t))


[0110] and fit the model




r
(t)=X(t)f(t)+ε(t)



[0111] then
6f(t)=(f1(t)f2(t))andε(t)=(ε1(t)ε2(t))


[0112] If we assume the factor exposures capture all sources of common return between any two assets then the covariance matrix


Δ(t)=cov(ε(t),ε(t))


[0113] continues to be diagonal and in fact
7Δ(t)=(Δ1(t)00Δ2(t))


[0114] The covariance matrix of common factor returns




F
(t)=cov(f(t),f(t))



[0115] is
8F(t)=(F1(t)F12(t)F12(t)tF2(t))


[0116] where F1(t) and F2(t) are as given in the local market models and




F


12
(t)=cov(f1(t),f2(t))



[0117] is a new piece of data. Thus, (X(t), F(t), Δ(t)) constitutes a factor model for the union of the two local markets. In particular, the asset-by-asset covariance matrix Ω(t) for the combination of the two markets is given by


Ω(t)=X(t)F(t)X(t)t+Δ(t)


[0118] Given Ω(t), risk analysis may be performed on the union of the two markets exactly as it is performed on each market separately. Hence, in summary, we see that the only new piece of information required to join (X1, F1, Δ1) and (X2, F2, Δ2) into (X(t), F(t), A(t)) is F12(t).


[0119] Let us consider how we might estimate F12(t). The simplest approach is to form the sample covariance matrix




{circumflex over (F)}


12
(t)=cov({f1(u),f2(u)}u=1t)



[0120] For combining just two models this approach might be adequate. However, the presently preferred embodiment of the invention may be used to combine 50 or so models, with each model containing, e.g. 40 factors. Thus, we could face up to 2000 factors. Computing a 2000 times 2000 sample covariance matrix from limited time series data leads to degenerate results.


[0121] In short, combining factor models has led us to exactly the same problem we faced when we tried to compute asset-by-asset covariance matrices directly. In the asset case we saw that the solution was a factor model. Hence, we turn to a factor model to solve our present difficulty. In particular, we identify factors g(t) that capture the covariance between f1(t) and f2(t). Let Y(t) be the exposures of
9f(t)=(f1(t)f2(t))tog(t).


[0122] Then




f
(t)=Y(t)g(t)+φ(t)



[0123] Then we can form




G
(t)=cov(g(t),g(t))



Φ(t)=cov(φ(t),φ(t))


[0124] and take as our initial estimate of F(t)




{tilde over (F)}
(t)=Y(t)G(t)Y(t)t+Φ(t)



[0125] Assuming that the exposures in Y(t) capture all sources of common covariance between f1(t) and f2(t), Φ(t) is a block diagonal matrix with the form
10Φ(t)=(Φ1(t)00Φ2(t))


[0126] Let




H
(t)=Y(t)G(t)Y(t)t



[0127] which we write in block form as
11H(t)=(H1(t)H12(t)H12(t)tH2(t))


[0128] similarly we write
12F~(t)=(F~1(t)F~12(t)F~12(t)F~2(t))


[0129] Then on the diagonal blocks




{tilde over (F)}


i
(t)=Hi(t)+Φi(t)



[0130] and on the off-diagonal block




{tilde over (F)}


12
(t)=H12(t)



[0131] Assuming we have found the correct factor structure, as the sample size goes to infinity, one has {tilde over (F)}i(t) converge to Fi(t). With finite samples, however, this convergence may be incomplete. We may rescale {tilde over (F)} to bring its diagonal blocks into agreement with the blocks P provided by the local models. Let M1/2 indicate the singular value square root of the matrix M. Introduce
13R=((F1)12(F~1)-1200(F2)12(F~2)-12)


[0132] Then




{circumflex over (F)}=R{tilde over (F)}R


t




[0133] is an estimator of F such that its diagonal blocks {circumflex over (F)}i are identical with the blocks provided by the local market model. Note that as {tilde over (F)}1 converges to Fi the resealing matrix R converges to the identity. We take {circumflex over (F)} as our final estimate of F. In particular its off-diagonal block {circumflex over (F)}12 is
14F^12=(F1)12(F~1)-12F~12(F~2t)-12(F2)12=(F1)12(H1+Φ1)-12H12(H2+Φ2)-12(F2)12


[0134] To summarize the discussion, we saw that F12 was the information required to combine the two local market models and that its estimator {circumflex over (F)}12 can be constructed from the given data F1 and F2 plus the additional data H and Φ derived from the factor model




f
(t)=Y(t)g(t)+φ(t)



[0135] The foregoing describes a completely general approach to combining two factor models. The foregoing technique, however, is not restricted to combining just two models. One could combine any number of local market models (Xi(t), Fi(t), Δi(t)) given a suitable factor model (Y, G, Φ). Thus, we have in fact described a mechanism for modeling the entire universe of investable assets. The essential property of this construction is that it integrates the detailed analysis of a local market into a global analysis. In particular, if h is a portfolio which happens to lie in a local market, then the risk analysis of h conducted in the local context is identical with the analysis of h conducted in the global framework.


[0136] Local Models


[0137] Let us apply the above discussion to the formulation of a global equity analysis. Following the formulation of the Global Equity Model we can decompose the excess return ri, num(t) to asset i in numeraire currency into its local excess return ri, loc(t) and its currency return ri, curcur(t) as




r


i, num
(t)=ri, loc(t)+ri, cur(t)



[0138] To achieve a global analysis we require local models for the equity asset returns and for the currency returns. Fortunately, we have a large number of such models already constructed. The following discussion briefly describes these models.


[0139] For the local analysis of an equity market we employ a factor structure containing two types of factors: industries and risk indices. The definition of the industry factors begins with the choice of an industrial classification system. While the precise definitions are usually chosen so as to be appropriate to the local market, the categories are sufficiently broad and distinct as to be largely similar from country to country. Once the classification system is defined, each company is assigned an industry exposure. Always the industry exposures of a company sum to not more than one. In some models, exposures are zero-one variables, so a company has an exposure of one to one industry and zero to all others. In other models, companies are exposed to multiple industries. In this case, the industry exposures are assigned to capture the importance of that industry to the company. The assignment is usually made based on a combination of accounting data, i.e. sales in a business segment, and a style analysis of company returns against industry index returns.


[0140] The risk indices capture other aspects of a security which are useful to understanding its return pattern. Examples of such indices are measures of size, liquidity, value, yield, exposure to foreign trade, blue chip quality, membership in indices on which futures contracts trade, past market performance, and volatility. Each local model contains a set of risk indices appropriate to that market and with definitions more or less specialized to the data available in that market. The construction of the indices follows a general pattern however. First a concept is identified, e.g. size. Then specific pieces of data (known as descriptors) are identified which have a bearing on the concept, for instance market capitalization or revenues. The descriptors are then combined to form a factor exposure which seems maximally informative about return patterns. For instance, one might take a linear combination of the descriptors where the coefficient attached to a descriptor could be interpreted as a measure of how accurately the descriptor realizes the concept. The need to handle the problems of missing data, outliers, and changing accounting definitions through time tends to make the details of factor exposure construction rather complex. Continuous factor exposures are usually standardized against the local asset universe, a step which makes the factor exposures comparable from factor to factor. Discrete factor exposures, e.g. a zero-one variable indicating membership in an index portfolio, are usually left unstandardized. Factor exposures are revised as new information arrives. For instance, if a company sells a division its industry exposures may differ after that point from those before that point.


[0141] Once the factor exposure matrix X has been defined, the factor returns and specific returns are measured through the regression




r
(t)=X(t)f(t)+ε(t)



[0142] Different models generally employ a weighting scheme suitable to the local market, e.g. capitalization weighting or GLS weights. From returns data one constructs the covariance matrices F(t) and Δ(t). In some models, however, there is considerable detail to this construction.


[0143] In investigating factor structures we have found them to differ along time and capitalization dimensions. Thus, in the U.S., for instance, we actually estimate three separate models—a model of large capitalization stocks based on monthly returns, a model of large capitalization stocks based on daily returns, and a model of small capitalization stocks based on monthly returns. In Europe, we estimate models for many of the individual national markets. However, we also estimate a pan-European model. As we have noted, a factor model should be fit over a homogenous group of assets. There are degrees of homogeneity and how much homogeneity a group of assets exhibits depends in part on one's perspective. For some investors, European equities as a whole currently represent a homogenous group, while other investors follow strategies which continue to see the national markets as the primary homogenous groups.


[0144] Our global analysis is constructed by combining local models. The wealth of local models gives us considerable flexibility in producing a global analysis. For instance, we can combine local models estimated over daily time horizons to achieve a global analysis suitable for short-term risk assessment. Alternatively, we can combine local models estimated for small capitalization stocks to produce a global small capitalization analysis. In treating European assets we can choose to combine several nationally focused local models, or instead we can use our European region model.


[0145] In addition to local equity models we also require a model of currency returns. Our currency model is an example of a degenerate factor model in that it has one factor per currency. In other words, the exposure matrix X is the identity, so the asset returns equal the factor returns and the specific returns are zero. The subtlety of the model comes in how the factor covariance matrix is constructed. We write




F


ij
iσjρij



[0146] where σi is the volatility of currency i and ρij is the correlation between currencies i and j. The volatilities σi are estimated from GARCH models chosen appropriately for each currency model fit over fairly high frequency data. The correlations are estimated by an exponentially weighted moving average method applied to lower frequency data. Additional detail has been provided by Goldberg (see Currency Risk Modeling, Barra 2000 Research Seminar, Section C).


[0147] The Equity Covariance Structure


[0148] Methodology


[0149] Given the local models, our task now is to construct the global model which unifies them. Hence, the first order of business is to determine the global factor structure Y. We focus first on the factors relating local equity markets. Our research on global equity factors has already identified a number of possible factors (See Table 1):


[0150] 1. Country factors and a world factor;


[0151] 2. Global Industry factors;


[0152] 3. Global risk under factor;


[0153] 4. A global macro-economic factor.


[0154] The global macroeconomic factor is a new element given the current structure of equity risk models. It is formed from two descriptors. The first descriptor is the country's inflation rate standardized cross-sectionally. The second descriptor is the ratio of the country's current account to its reserve bank holdings of foreign exchange, also standardized cross-sectionally. The factor is defined as the difference of these two descriptors standardized cross-sectionally. Thus, this factor is sensitive to either internal or external monetary disequilibrium. Reflecting its definition, we term this factor Gloom & Doom.
1TABLE 1Final Factor SelectionNumberTypeFactors 1World Equity FactorWorld22CountriesAustralia, Brazil, Canada,France, Germany, Greece,Hong Kong, Indonesia,Japan,Korea, Malaysia, Mexico,Netherlands, New Zealand,Singapore, South Africa,Sweden, Switzerland,Taiwan, Thailand, UnitedKingdom, United States19Global IndustriesAirlines, Automobiles,Banks, Beverage, Tobacco,Electronics, Energy,Financial Services, Food,Health, InformationTechnology, Insurance,Media, Mining, PreciousMetals, Property, RawMaterials, Technology,Telephone, Utilities 3Risk IndicesSize, Momentum, Volatility 1Macro Economic FactorGloom & Doom46Factors Total


[0155] Having determined the factor concepts, we must next specify the factor loadings. Let


[0156] mi(t)=return to market portfolio of country i


[0157] fji(t)=return to jth factor of country i


[0158] βji(t)=factor beta of fji(t)with respect to mi(t) predicted by the local model for country i


[0159] Di1(t)=1 for all i


[0160] Di2(t)=the Gloom & Doom exposure for country i
15Dijk3(t)={1jisanindustryintheithcountrybelongingtothekthglobalindustry0OtherwiseDijk4(t)={1jisariskindexintheithcountrybelongingtothekthglobalriskindex0Otherwise


[0161] We have in essence two models. The first model is




m


i
(t)=Di1(t){tilde over (g)}1(t)+Di2(t){tilde over (g)}2(t)+ci(t)



[0162] where


[0163] {tilde over (g)}1(t)=World Equity return


[0164] {tilde over (g)}2(t)=Gloom & Doom return


[0165] ci(t)=return to country i active to the World return and the Gloom and Doom return


[0166] Note that Σici(t)=0 by construction. The second model is
16fji(t)-βji(t)mi(t)=kDijk3(t)g~3k(t)+jDijl4(t)g~4l(t)+φij(t)


[0167] where


[0168] {tilde over (g)}3k(t)=is the return to the kth global industry


[0169] {tilde over (g)}4l(t)=is the return to the lth global risk index


[0170] φij(t)=is the purely local part of the return fji(t)


[0171] Substituting the first model into the second and rearranging terms we get
17fji(t)=k-146Yjki(t)gk(t)+φji(t)


[0172] by setting


[0173] Yj1i(t)=βji(t) the World exposure


[0174] Yj2i(t)=βji(t)Di2(t) the Gloom & Doom exposure


[0175] while for k=3, 4, . . . 24,


[0176] Yjki(t)=βjk−2(t) the country exposure


[0177] and for k=25, 26, . . . 43,
18Yjki(t)={1jisanindustrybelongingtothe(K-24)thglobalindustry0Otherwise


[0178] and finally, for k=44 . . . 46,
19Yjki(t)={1jisariskindexbelongingtothe(k-43)rdglobalriskindex0Otherwise


[0179] These equations define the global factor loadings.


[0180] In this notation the restriction is
20k=324gk(t)=0


[0181] In other words, we force the country factor returns to be active to the combination of the World return and Gloom & Doom. With this constraint imposed, the model is now fully identified and may be estimated by a cross-sectional regression for each time period t.


[0182] Construction of the Equity Covariance Matrix


[0183] Our next task is to generate a covariance matrix G of global factor returns. Here, we face the difficulty that our local models begin at different dates. Consequently, the country factor returns which we are able to estimate have different starting dates. It is desirable that all the time series entering the covariance matrix estimation have the same length. Accordingly, we need to extend some of the country factor return series backwards in time. Our solution is to proxy the missing country factor return data with data derived from a local market return index. Once all the time-series have been completed to the same length we form the exponentially weighted expanding window sample covariance matrix. In other words, the matrix estimated at time t uses all information from periods prior to t with data n periods in the past being weighted by αn for α a suitable constant. We pick α to have a 90 month half-life, i.e. α=0.5. The exponentially weighted estimate has approximately the same statistical weight as an equal weighted moving window estimate with window width 1/(1−α). For α90=0.5 the equivalent equal weighted window has a width of 130 months. We prefer an exponentially weighted expanding window to an equal weighted moving window because it permits outlier observations to fade away gradually, whereas the moving window method causes outliers to generate artificial shocks as the far edge of the window frame moves past them.


[0184] The Currency-Equity Covariance Structure


[0185] We now turn to the currency part of the global equity model. There are two sets of covariances. We must estimate currency-to-currency covariances and currency-to-equity covariances. The currency-to-currency part is immediately disposed of by our currency model. Hence, it is enough to consider covariances between currency returns and local equity factor returns. In modeling the relationship between equity factors and currencies, our first observation is that the dimensionalities are such that a simple historical covariance matrix contains many spurious correlation. Accordingly, a more structured approach is required.


[0186] We identified four factors which could link equity and currency returns. The first factor is an indicator variable for Russian distress. It is defined as
21c1(t)={1ifr(t)<2σ(t)0otherwise


[0187] where r(t) is the ruble-dollar exchange rate return and σ(t) is an exponentially weighted estimator of the standard deviation of that return. The other three factors, c2 (t), c3 (t) and c4 (t) are defined for each country as the exchange return between local currency and dollar, Euro, and pound, respectively.


[0188] For each equity factor f(t) we selected the best single factor model of the form




f
(t)=α+βci(t)+ε(t)



[0189] for i ranging from one to four. Here, f was taken to range over both size and market factors. However, no size factor led to a meaningful result and only results for the market factor are tabulated. The results are shown in Table 2. We also considered the best two factor model, however, no two factor model was meaningfully superior to the one factor mode. In considering two factor models we had to disallow the combination of c3 and c4 due to multicolinearity. The cases which result in non-negligible R2 with reasonably significant T-statistics on beta in general seem economically intuitive. They are listed in Table 3.


[0190] Using these relationships between equity and currency returns, we may now derive a consistent covariance structure connecting any equity factor and currency exchange rate.
2TABLE 2Market-Currency Modelsmodelcountryfactorsinterceptβ1β2tintert1t2R2Adj. R2Australiac30.008−0.14.1.462−0.99.0.019−0Brazilc30.005−0.49.0.405−3.02.0.1520.135Canadac10.0150.045.2.1411.931.0.0760.056Francec40.0140.632.2.3992.518.0.1110.093Francec1/c40.0190.0360.5322.471.3151.7280.1330.089Germanyc40.0120.641.1.6071.958.0.070.052Germanyc1/c40.0160.0450.5431.6131.281.3760.1040.058Greecec40.0240.185.1.8020.383.0.003−0.01Hong Kongc3−0−0.39.−0.04−0.73.0.01−0.01Indonesiac30.006−0.61.0.351−1.1.0.0230.004Japanc40.0010.168.0.1871.043.0.0180.001Koreac1−0.01−0.08.−0.3−1.51.0.0490.027Malaysiac10.0020.079.0.1161.408.0.0430.021Malaysiac1/c30.0070.113−0.290.2971.617−0.910.0650.015Mexicoc30.004−0.58.0.403−2.8.0.1380.121Mexicoc2/c3−01.221−1.36−0.122.278−3.430.2220.19Netherlandsc40.0151.022.2.2473.665.0.2080.193Netherlandsc1/c40.0150.0241.0751.7540.7633.0730.230.19New Zealandc20.0020.379.0.3081.53.0.0390.022New Zealandc3/c4−0−0.670.776−0.3−2.352.6450.1290.095South Africac163E-50.064.0.0631.854.0.0710.05South Africac2/c3−0.011.035−0.76−0.762.483−2.220.1170.081Singaporec4 8E-40.364.0.0750.85.0.012−0Swedenc40.020.5533.0662.1350.0730.057Switzerlandc40.0130.5672.2182.6670.1090.094Taiwanc3−0.01−0.44−0.83−1.340.0340.015Thailandc2−0.01−0.56−1.01−2.280.0820.067Thailandc1/c2−0.02−0.01−0.52−0.94−0.21−1.510.0880.047United Kingdomc30.005−0.481.05−2.320.0950.077United Kingdomc1/c30.0060.037−0.40.921.646−1.580.1460.103United Statesc10.0140.0332.0781.3750.040.019United Statesc1/c30.0150.029−0.341.9651.171−1.130.0860.039


[0191]

3





TABLE 3










Significant Market-Currency Models












Currency
Country
R2adj
|T − stat on β|
















Dollar
New Zealand
2.2
1.5



Dollar
Thailand
6.7
2.3



Euro
Brazil
13.5
3.0



Euro
Mexico
12.1
2.8



Euro
United Kingdom
7.7
2.3



Pound
France
9.3
2.5



Pound
Germany
5.2
2.0



Pound
Netherlands
19.3
3.7



Pound
Sweden
5.7
2.1



Pound
Switzerland
9.4
2.7



Ruble
Canada
5.6
1.9



Ruble
Malaysia
2.1
1.9



Ruble
South Africa
5.0
1.9











[0192] Let




f
(t)=α+βc(t)+ε(t)



[0193] be the fitted model for some market. If {tilde over (f)}(t) is a second equity factor in that market and {tilde over (c)}(t) is a second currency factor we assume that the covariance between {tilde over (f)}(t) and {tilde over (c)}(t) derives from the linkage through f(t) and c(t). Then




{tilde over (f)}
(t)=α11f(t)+ε1(t)





{tilde over (c)}
(t)=α22c(t)+ε2(t)



[0194] and thus




cov
({tilde over (f)},{tilde over (c)})=β1β2cov(f,c)



1β2βvar(c)


[0195] Here, only the quantity β is actually estimated. The quantities β1, β2 and var(c) are calculated from the equity and currency covariance matrices respectively. In this way, we may compute the covariance block between the currencies and local equity markets.


[0196] The Total Covariance Structure


[0197] Let i=0 indicate currencies and for i>0 let i denote the ith local equity market. We have described the construction of the covariance block Ci,j giving the covariances between the factors of the ith and jth markets. We assemble these blocks into a large covariance matrix {tilde over (F)} where
22F~=(C0,0C0,1C0,2C0,nC1,0tC1,1C1,2C1,n)


[0198] This is our preliminary estimate of the common factor covariance matrix. We rescale it as described above to bring the diagonal blocks to their target values, thus achieving our final estimate of common factor covariance matrix {circumflex over (F)}. This completes our construction of the New Global Equity Model.


[0199] Properties and Applications of the Model


[0200] Having formulated the Global Equity Model, it is of interest to probe the model's properties and to apply this new tool to some questions in global equity analysis.


[0201] Properties of the Global Model


[0202] We first consider the fit of the model. FIG. 1 shows the monthly R2 of the model, together with a six month moving average. While model fit varies from month to month, average fit is stable. Summary statistics on fit are given in Table 4. There is no statistically significant variation in the level of fit between in-sample and out-of-sample periods. Note that the average level of fit is 68%, as compared with a typical value of 30% for single country equity factor models. The higher fit in the global model can be understood as the model is fit at the factor return level rather than at the asset level.
4TABLE 4Properties of Model Fit (R2)(April 1978-December 1999)Mean0.68minimum0.28median0.6825% tile0.57standard deviation0.1475% tile0.77interquartile range0.20maximum0.94Model Fit for Various SubperiodsPeriodmean R2 (%)April 1978-December 199267January 1993-December 199868January 1994-December 199963


[0203]
FIG. 2 plots monthly fit against the absolute return to the world factor. Just as the fit of local models improves in months when there is a strong local market effect, so the fit of the global model improves in months when there is a strong world market effect. In fact, the regression




R


2
(t)=α+β|w(t)|+ε(t)



[0204] on the absolute world return w(t) has the properties shown in Table 5. In particular, the magnitude of the world return explains 37% of the variation in the fit of the global model.
5TABLE 5Relationship of Model Fit to Absolute World Return(estimated over April 1978 to December 1999)parameterstandard errort-statprob tα0.530.01148.80.0001β3.760.30 12.40.0001


[0205] In Table 6 we show for each global factor some summary statistics on its t-statistic. Excepting the risk indices, every factor is clearly significant judged by the absolute value of the t-statistic being greater than two more often than can be explained by chance. Of the three risk indices, Momentum is marginally significant by this test, whereas Size and Volatility are not. The low level of significance for the risk indices provides some validation for our choice of cut-off in the factor selection process. Shortly, we shall present evidence that Size and Volatility are highly correlated with the World factor. This finding suggests that at the global level these factors have been cannibalized by the World factor. The interesting implication is that at the local level these factors may be picking up a projection of the World factor into the national market. Certainly for Size this would be a credible interpretation. This thought provides an interesting side light on the work of Chaumeton and Coldiron on the one hand and Chandrashekaran, Hui, and Rudd on the other. These investigators searched for a global company factor, but were stymied by the sought for factor apparently being confounded with the size factor. Perhaps the global company factor and the size factor should be seen as imperfect descriptions of the same concept, rather than as confounded factors.
6TABLE 6Absolute Values of Factor t-statistics(January 1993 to December 1998)95thFactor% time |t-stat| > 290th PercentilePercentileWorld85.120.024.1Australia67.69.212.5Brazil69.210.112.7Canada78.19.912.0France55.55.97.0Germany60.88.610.6Greece62.99.012.7Hong Kong72.210.413.7Indonesia77.111.016.6Japan83.515.318.8Korea86.217.721.7Malaysia70.013.516.5Mexico81.99.010.0Netherlands50.65.36.4New Zealand45.75.26.3Singapore68.59.610.8South Africa84.514.015.7Sweden71.210.011.9Switzerland57.06.07.2Taiwan88.022.131.9Thailand81.514.717.1United Kingdom74.110.113.7United States75.911.313.2Airlines21.52.93.2Autos8.41.92.3Banks20.72.83.3Beverage & Tobacco17.62.52.7Electronics16.92.32.9Energy52.94.95.9Financial Services19.92.43.1Food9.61.92.4Health18.82.42.9Information Technology18.82.93.4Insurance26.42.93.3Media16.12.22.6Mining20.32.63.3Precious Metals63.27.19.6Property16.12.33.0Raw Materials10.32.02.3Technology18.02.73.2Telephones18.42.53.0Utilities18.42.63.3Momentum5.41.72.0Size2.71.51.8Volatility0.71.11.4Gloom & Doom9.51.92.5


[0206] A key assumption of our model is that the global factor structure Y accounts for all significant covariances between local models. An implication is that the sample covariance matrix
23Φij(t)=cov({φi(u),φj(u)}u=1t)


[0207] should be block diagonal. We test this hypothesis by computing the mean of the cells of the off-diagonal blocks in Φ and also the mean magnitude of these off diagonal cells. FIG. 3 shows these quantities calculated from a 60 month moving window. In the early period some spikes are evident. These spikes are data artifacts occasioned by the entrance of new models into the analysis and hence the calculation of correlation of very short time series, leading to spuriously high values. Note that the imposition of a block diagonal structure on Φ filters these artifacts out of the final model. Looking at the more recent history we see that the level of correlation is low and very stable. The mean value is −0.0003 and the mean magnitude is 0.11. These values are consistent with the hypothesis that the purely local factor returns are uncorrelated across countries. The stability of these values argues against a recent change in the global factor structure.


[0208] To summarize the discussion to this point, the global model fits well, appears free of degenerate behavior, and conforms to the posited model structure.


[0209] Properties of the Global Factors


[0210] We turn from a consideration of the model as a whole to a consideration of the properties of its factors. Table 7 summarizes the important time-series properties of the model's factors. The typical factor appears to be an independent identically distributed normal variable with mean close to 0 and standard deviation of about 3% per month. Some notable exceptions to this pattern occur however:


[0211] 1) The World exhibits excess kurtosis and has a mean return of 0.5% per month.


[0212] 2) The emerging market countries have standard deviations in the range of 6-12%. Several of them exhibit either more kurtosis or more conditional heteroscedasticity than is consistent with homoscedastic normality.


[0213] 3) Mining and Precious Metals exhibit more skewness and kurtosis than is consistent with normality. However, they do appear homoscedastic. Information Technology and Technology show both high mean returns and high information ratio. Health and Media also exhibit high information ratios on somewhat lower returns. Energy, Telephones, and Utilities may exhibit some serial correlation in returns.


[0214] 4) Momentum is non-normal and shows some serial correlation.


[0215] 5) Gloom & Doom shows striking levels of skewness, kurtosis, serial correlation, and heteroscedasticity.
7TABLE 7Time Series Properties of Factor Returns(January 1990-January 2000)SERSER2CORRCORRFactorMEANSTDSKEWNESSKURTOSISPROBNRATIO(%)(%)World0.523.97−1.426.110.0013164Australia−0.214.420.101.6653.41−5−99Brazil0.199.671.314.010.1022711Canada−0.372.800.09−0.0751.50−133−5France0.453.580.361.0675.51131822Germany0.204.67−0.572.025.264826Greece0.268.611.062.540.0131716Hong Kong0.436.89−0.103.570.016535Indonesia−0.069.500.392.167.66−146Japan−0.244.520.151.1166.30−5016Korea−0.309.381.325.790.00−3−7−1Malaysia−0.118.980.791.950.06−1−715Mexico−0.275.87−0.761.898.00−5213Netherlands0.343.08−0.711.966.101177NewZealand−0.284.110.832.397.24−73−6Singapore−0.065.100.142.5724.61−11216South Africa−0.154.21−0.420.4257.48−441Sweden0.284.840.273.5872.0361−2Switzerland0.223.14−0.190.7994.047118Taiwan0.2711.060.452.410.192941Thailand−0.737.970.370.7866.95−9156United Kingdom−0.033.080.301.3090.35−1−3−6United States0.192.360.380.8535.888−44Airlines0.203.650.250.0424.3464−7Autos−0.181.590.180.9965.22−1151Banks0.151.820.571.660.8281620Beverage &0.171.54−0.070.0795.77112113TobaccoElectronics0.301.690.511.167.30181231Energy0.133.680.401.0827.5643422Financial Services0.191.340.331.184.97141616Food−0.111.220.021.0472.63−9218Health0.341.530.031.1687.78221530Information0.752.970.651.340.09251927TechnologyInsurance0.091.830.000.8499.4551712Media0.441.430.091.5564.9231166Mining−0.071.781.113.850.00−484Precious Metals0.508.931.183.980.0066−1Property−0.201.100.281.5095.85−18124Raw Materials−0.091.110.540.868.73−9623Technology0.933.000.883.703.76311422Telephones0.252.040.510.967.13122420Utilities−0.091.960.471.541.17−4266Momentum0.060.69−0.823.300.0093013Size−0.040.580.110.3796.45−7−213Volatility0.010.770.191.410.321−813Gloom & Doom−0.020.66−5.4350.570.00−33748std = standard deviation probn = probability factor returns are normally distributed ratio = mean/std ser corr = serial correlation of factor returns ser2 corr = serial correlation of squared factor returns


[0216] Here we call attention to several of the more interesting comparisons. FIG. 4 shows the cumulative factor returns for the World and the mean country returns for developed and emerging markets. Since 1992, emerging and developed markets have trended in somewhat opposite directions, thus muting the trend in the World.


[0217]
FIG. 5 breaks the developed region down into the U.S., Japan and Europe. Until recently, the basic pattern has been for Europe and the U.S. to trend upwards and Japan downwards. The latest data may not conform to this pattern, however.


[0218]
FIG. 6 compares the Asian and Latin American emerging markets. In both regions we see a pattern of stability, brief upward tick, decline, collapse, and recovery. However, the amplitudes and turning points associated with each subperiod seem distinct.


[0219]
FIG. 7 shows three financial industries. While interest rate and credit cycles broadly affect all three, insurance is in addition exposed to the underwriting cycle, and we note a recent divergence between insurance and the other two.


[0220] Three extractive industries are shown in FIG. 8. Here, we see Precious Metals to be in a prolonged bear market. By contrast, Energy is trending gradually upwards and Mining is trending gradually downwards with a cyclical modulation.


[0221] The three risk indices are shown in FIG. 9. The trend in Momentum makes a strong contrast with the aimless behavior of the other two.


[0222] By contrast, the technology industries shown in FIG. 10 have enjoyed a significant advance. The emergence of a strong trend in Telephones is more recent than in the other two.


[0223] Finally, FIG. 11 shows the Gloom & Doom factor. Here, the importance of point events to the factor return is notable. Thus, visual inspection confirms the impression formed from Table 7 that each factor return has its distinctive characteristics.


[0224] The average correlation between different groups of factors are given in Table 8. Except for the World-Risk Index correlation, most cross-group correlation are on average small. Note that industries and countries are more correlated within themselves than with other groups. Additional insight into the factor covariance structure can be gleaned from Table 9, which shows for each factor its volatility and most important correlation. In general, the correlation are quite intuitive. For countries regional groupings emerge (Table 10), but the correlation remain sufficiently low that we do not find a need to replace country concepts with regional concepts. Looking at subperiods, increasing integration within the European region is particularly notable. Similarly industries tend to correlate within sector groupings, but again the correlation are not so strong as to suggest replacing industry concepts with sector concepts.
8TABLE 8Mean Correlations Between Classes of Factors(excluding self correlations, in percent, for January 1999)WorldCountriesIndustriesRisk Indicescountries4.6−3.6−0.11.0industries−110.113.84.0risk indices36.41.04.07.1Gloom & Doom1.41.00.9−5.8


[0225]

9





TABLE 9








Factor Volatility (%/pa) and Three Factors with Largest


Absolute Correlations (%) for each Factor as of January 1999






















World
14
Volatility
75
Utilities
−58
Size
51


Australia
15
New Zealand
51
South Africa
−32
Indonesia
−30


Brazil
34
Mexico
42
United States
−33
United
−29








Kingdom


Canada
10
United States
43
Taiwan
−42
Japan
−30


France
12
Greece
55
Netherlands
54
Switzerland
38


Germany
16
France
55
Netherlands
50
Switzerland
46


Greece
30
Automobiles
30
France
28
Switzerland
24


Hong Kong
24
Malaysia
51
Singapore
51
France
−28


Indonesia
33
United Kingdom
−40
World
36
Malaysia
32


Japan
16
United States
−32
Malaysia
−30
Canada
−30


Korea
32
France
−34
Australia
−27
Greece
−26


Malaysia
31
Singapore
51
Hong Kong
51
Thailand
45


Mexico
20
Brazil
42
Technology
−26
World
19


Netherlands
11
France
54
Switzerland
54
Greece
50


New Zealand
14
Australia
51
Sweden
22
Taiwan
−22


Singapore
18
Malaysia
51
Hong Kong
51
Volatility
39


South Africa
15
Utilities
−37
Australia
−32
Property
−30


Sweden
17
France
32
Netherlands
30
South Africa
−29


Switzerland
11
Netherlands
53
Greece
46
Malaysia
−41


Taiwan
38
Canada
−42
United States
−33
Netherlands
−32


Thailand
28
Malaysia
45
Volatility
33
World
32


United Kingdom
34
Indonesia
−39
Brazil
−29
Taiwan
−27


United States
8
Canada
43
Japan
−34
Brazil
−33


Airlines
13
Indonesia
−28
Australia
−19
Energy
−18


Automobiles
6
Greece
30
New Zealand
20
Mexico
−18


Banks
6
Insurance
51
Financial
48
Utilities
34






Services


Beverage &
5
Food
46
Utilities
41
Health
41


Tobacco


Electronics
6
Volatility
27
Information
26
Indonesia
24






Technology


Energy
13
Precious Metals
27
Utilities
25
Property
23


Financial Services
5
Insurance
52
Banks
45
Indonesia
25


Food
4
Utilities
50
Beverage &
46
World
−40






Tobacco


Health
5
Beverage &
41
Food
37
Utilities
34




Tobacco


Information
10
Technology
28
Telephones
28
Electronics
26


Technology


Insurance
6
Financial Services
52
Banks
51
Food
36


Media
5
Telephones
32
Taiwan
−19
South Africa
19


Mining
6
Precious Metals
39
Malaysia
28
Brazil
27


Precious Metals
31
Mining
39
Energy
27
France
−28


Property
4
South Africa
−31
Energy
23
Japan
23


Raw Materials
4
France
−27
Mining
27
Malaysia
26


Technology
10
Information
29
Mexico
−26
Electronics
20




Technology


Telephones
7
Utilities
42
Media
32
World
−28


Utilities
7
World
−58
Food
48
Telephone
42


Momentum
2
Singapore
−33
Malaysia
−30
Hong Kong
−24


Size
2
World
51
Volatility
44
Thailand
31


Volatility
3
World
75
Size
44
Singapore
39


Gloom & Doom
2
Brazil
21
Technology
−16
Energy
−16










[0226]

10





TABLE 10








Regional Correlations
















AUSNZ:
Australia, New Zealand


Asia ex Japan:
Hong Kong, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand, Indonesia,



Korea, Taiwan


Europe:
France, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland,



United Kingdom


Latin America:
Brazil, Mexico


North America:
Canada, United States










Mean pairwise correlations between groups,


December 1987-December 1999, in


percent

















North


Region
AUSNZ
Asia
Europe
Latin America
America





AUSNZ
49
−15
8
−11
13


Asia

41
−22
2
−17


Europe


32
−6
−3


Latin America



42
−12


North America




50










Mean within group pairwise correlation


by subperiod, in percent









Region
Dec. 1989-Dec. 1994
Dec. 1994-Dec. 1999





AUSNZ
53
44


Asia
34
41


Europe
19
44


Latin America
63
43


North America
42
58










[0227] Properties of the Purely Local Factors


[0228] A new analytical concept introduced with the model is that of the purely local factor return. We may investigate the structures which it reveals in several ways. First, for each country we would like to form a measure of how much of the variability in that market derives from purely local factors. For a covariance matrix M the total variation statistic is tr M (trace of M). It gives a measure of how much variability there is in the covariance structure described by M. The quantity tr Φi/tr Fi suggests itself as such a measure of the relative level of purely local variation in market i. As a tool for making comparisons among countries, however, this measure proves not entirely suitable. The difficulty is that Fi contains the variability due to the country market return, while ρi does not. As market volatility varies strongly across countries, this effect confounds the attempt to use tr Φi/tr Fi as a measure of how important the purely local effects are in country i. Accordingly, we introduce a modified measure. Let λ1i be the largest eigenvalue of Fi. Then λ1i essentially represents the variability of the market return in country i. We take




L


i
(t)=trΦi(t)/[trFi(t)−λ1i(t)]



[0229] as our measure of how important the local factors are in country i at time t. Table 11 tabulates these ratios.
11TABLE 11Fraction of Total Variation in each Market due to Purely LocalFactors, as of January 2000Countrytr Φitr Fi − λ1iLi (t)Taiwan0.0873 0.061581.42New Zealand0.005220.003931.33Brazil0.085940.077451.11Malaysia0.034390.032071.07Japan0.051930.048741.07Mexico0.011910.011251.06Australia0.030120.028841.04Thailand0.203430.194991.04Germany0.023530.023860.99Greece0.052640.054670.96Indonesia0.079560.085280.93Sweden0.030280.032590.93Switzerland0.009590.010330.93Netherlands0.004470.004870.92Singapore0.029570.032710.90Korea0.097320.107660.90South Africa0.116770.130250.90Hong Kong0.024680.029050.85France0.008810.010490.84United Kingdom0.042870.051510.83United States0.049550.070910.70Canada0.032280.047960.67


[0230] The table clearly shows that barely local factors come as significant source of risk for concentrated portfolios.


[0231] We may also study the pattern of purely local returns from a factor viewpoint. For each factor i we may take the ratio var(Φ1)/var(fi) as a measure of how local that factor is. Collecting the means of these ratios over factors of a given type, e.g. Technology or Size, we get a measure of how much local variation in behavior there is within the scope of a globally defined concept. Here, the results are presented in Table 12.
12TABLE 12Degree of Local Variation within Global Factors Based onVariance Estimates for January 1999, in percentUnited Kingdom76Aerospace50Momentum76Australia61Energy44Size75New Zealand61Precious Metals37Volatility70Taiwan58Technology37Greece54Utilities36Germany52Commercial Services32Netherlands49Computers31Switzerland49Telephones31South Africa47Banking29France46Insurance29Brazil45Property29Sweden45Health28Malaysia43Mining28Indonesia41Beverage & Tobacco27United States41Info. Technology27Thailand39Transportation27Canada38Electronics26Singapore37Airlines25Hong Kong35Media25Japan35Financial Services23Mexico34Services23Korea31Automobiles22Raw Materials21Business Services18Food18Chemicals17Construction16Industrials16


[0232] There is an important economic interpretation which can be put on the purely local factor return. Within a market these factor returns represent common risk factors which cannot be eliminated through diversification. For investors who operate globally, however, the purely local factor risk can be reduced by diversification across markets. The implications are two. First, markets where Li(t) are high are the markets in which the benefits of international diversification may be large. Second, the trend in Li(t) through time shows how these benefits have varied through time. In Table 13 we present the results of the regression




L


i
(t)=α+βt+εi(t)



[0233] Some marked trends are evident. In particular, most markets appear to be trending towards lower values of Li(t). This finding could be interpreted as evidence of increasing global integration. However, we caution that the properties of Li(t) have not yet been investigated sufficiently in depth for us to lay much stress on this finding.
13TABLE 13Trend in Li (t) (estimated over January 1990-January 2000)t-statistics onmarketαβαβR2 (%)Australia1.20−0.0007152.1−7.026Brazil1.25−0.004491.7−7.259Canada0.77−0.0004108.8−5.116France0.850.000746.23.27Greece0.98−0.0070156.7−7.686Germany0.920.001444.46.821Hong Kong0.95−0.0037177.7−15.086Indonesia1.11−0.006787.8−11.279Japan0.480.003131.924.375Korea1.230.001830.13.79Malaysia1.19−0.0028319.2−21.591Mexico1.020.001024.41.32Netherlands1.28−0.004872.4−11.465New Zealand1.260.0008132.95.923South Africa1.01−0.0027196.9−14.983Singapore1.07−0.0062211.5−26.195Sweden0.98−0.0008109.0−6.424Switzerland1.02−0.0006284.7−11.953Thailand1.30−0.002951.4−4.624Taiwan1.280.0021203.713.673United Kingdom0.99−0.0005213.6−11.741United States0.620.0006269.528.781


[0234] We have not made any systematic investigation of the contribution of purely local common factors to performance. However, we have permitted ourselves a simple case study. We considered the MSCI U.S. index portfolio and decomposed its return over the October 1989-November 1999 period into various components. The results are given in Table 14. Unsurprisingly, the U.S. factor in the Global Equity Model contributed most of the returns. However, the return from purely local U.S. common factors was slightly greater than the contribution from the global industries and risk indices. The net contribution of the purely local factors was 1.9% per annum. Thus, purely local effects can make a meaningful contribution to performance. We note that the number of purely local effects is ten to twenty times the number of global effects. Thus, for equal skill in picking global and local factors, the fundamental law of active management favors strategies based on purely local factors over those based on global factors.
14TABLE 14Return Decomposition for the MSCI US Portfolio(October 1989 to November 1999, arithmetic excess returns)FactorCumulative Return (%)Mean Return (% pa)World10.51.0US95.56.9other global common19.71.8factorspurely local common20.91.9factorsspecific7.20.7total23512.9


[0235] Portfolio Analysis


[0236] Market Portfolios


[0237] Next, we turn to a consideration of portfolios. The simplest portfolio to consider is the market portfolio hml of country i. The analysis of this portfolio in the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 is identical with its analysis in the single country model for that country. By contrast, the analysis in the Global Equity Model is different. Table 15 compares the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 estimate of risk with the Global Equity Model estimate.
15TABLE 15Comparison of Country Variance Estimates(variances × 10,000 as of April 1999)Global EquityCountryModel Version 2.0Global Equity ModelAustralia223.3555.9Brazil1936.72473.7Canada277.0418.3France395.2326.7Greece1939.71597.2Hong Kong1517.71136.4Indonesia2691.83040.0Japan578.5810.7Malaysia1556.2810.7Mexico655.81429.4Netherlands335.3274.3New Zealand515.0625.8South Africa674.51183.5Singapore1314.4881.7Switzerland417.9422.1Thailand1619.01526.9Taiwan2376.32218.2United Kingdom300.6280.7United States221.8293.7


[0238] The next level of analysis considers the covariance between hml and h1 for two countries i and j. In the Global Equity Model Version 2.0, this measure probes the off diagonal block Cij. Table 16 presents the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 and the Global Equity Model analyses. It will be seen that the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 typically estimates a lower correlation, which implies a greater benefit from international diversification. Here, an important difference in the two analyses appears to be the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 recognition that much cross-market correlation derives from the world factor which displays pronounced conditional heteroscedasticity. By contrast, the Global Equity Model assumes a homoscedastic world. If we drop from the empirical data the months when the world return was greatest (October 1987, August 1998) and calculate the correlation of the empirical data series, we see that the Japan correlation in particular shift to being closer to the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 estimates than to the Global Equity Model estimates. However, other empirical correlation remain significantly higher than the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 estimates.
16TABLE 16Selected Country Correlations (as of April 1999, in percent)Global EquityGlobalModelEquityHistoric-country pairVersion 2.0ModelfilteredAustralia-Brazil113032Canada-United States286966France-United Kingdom295263Hong Kong-Japan33516Japan-United States253622Switzerland-Sweden94849United Kingdom-United States395956


[0239] A Case Study


[0240] To gain further insight we consider a simple case study. We take our investable universe to consist of just four stocks: Toyota, Mitsubishi Trust Bank, General Motors, and BankAmerica. We take the benchmark portfolio to be the equally weighted portfolio holding these four assets. We take the managed portfolio to consist equally of Mitsubishi Trust Bank and General Motors. Thus, the active portfolio, i.e. the difference between the managed portfolio and the benchmark, is:
17Toyota−25% Mitsubishi Trust Bank25%General Motors25%BankAmerica−25% 


[0241]

18





TABLE 17








Global Equity Model Risk Exposures


















Japan Market
0.20



US Market
−0.09



Size
0.48



Success
0.17



Value
0.07



Volatility in Markets
0.63











[0242] It will be noted that the active portfolio has no net exposure to Yen/Dollar, Japan/U.S. or Autos/Banks. We analyze the risks of the active portfolio in both the Global Equity Model and the Global Equity Model Version 2.0. In the Global Equity Model the risk exposures are as shown in Table 17.


[0243] It will be noted that the Global Equity Model perceives a country risk, despite there being no active distribution in portfolio wealth between countries, because the Global Equity Model calculates the country exposures based on historical beta and the betas of these assets are not all 1.0. In Table 18 we present the Global Equity Model risk decomposition.
19TABLE 18Global Equity Model Risk Decomposition(variance per month × 10,000)TypeRiskCommon Factor:risk indices2.6industries0.0countries22.9currencies0.02x covariance1.3Total26.8Specific156.6Total183.4


[0244] Most of the risk is specific. Such common factor risk as there is derives largely from the country exposures. Next, we turn to the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 analysis. As with the Global Equity Model, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 sees no currency exposure in the active portfolio. In other details, however, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 paints a significantly different picture. The risk exposures revealed by the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 are given in Table 19.
20TABLE 19Global Equity Model Version 2.0 Risk ExposuresJapan Local FactorsUS Local FactorsSystematic Variability0.39Volatility−0.03Size−0.33Momentum0.07Value−0.13Size−0.13Trading Activity0.21Size non-linearity−0.013Success−0.11Trading Activity0.07Interest Rate Sensitivity−0.03Growth−0.16Specific Variability0.18Earning Yield0.14Financial Leverage0.09Value0.24Growth−0.26Earnings Variability−0.04Foreign Sensitivity-1.08Leverage0.15TSE20Currency Sensitivity0.08Autos−0.25Yield−0.10Industrial Banks0.25Non-estimation Universe0.0Autos0.15Banks−0.25Financial Services0.10


[0245] Two exposures in particular are revealed which the Global Equity Model analysis missed. First, the Mitsubishi Trust Bank is more domestically focused than Toyota, so the active portfolio contains a significant tilt towards the Japanese domestic economy as revealed by the negative exposure to the foreign sensitivity risk index. Second, General Motors has significant exposure to the financial service industry through its credit corporation subsidiary, a fact which is captured by the multi-industry exposures supported by the USE3 model underlying the Global Equity Model Version 2.0. The Global Equity Model Version 2.0 risk decomposition is shown in Table 20.
21TABLE 20Global Equity Model Version 2.0 Risk DecompositionRiskJapanUSAllCommon FactorIndustries33.75.839.5Risk33.70.834.52x within market covariance18.60.018.62x cross market covariance−4.1Total Common Factor85.06.688.6Specific146.749.9196.5Total23.1756.5285.2


[0246] Superficially, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 analyses seems similar to the Global Equity Model analysis in that the estimated total active risk is roughly comparable in the two analyses (183.4 vs 285.2). Probing more deeply, however, we find striking differences in the risk decomposition. The common factor risk estimated by the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 is 88.6, more than three times the Global Equity Model estimate of 26.8. Most of this common factor risk derives from the Japan subportfolio, and may be attributed nearly equally to industry tilts and to risk index tilts. The unimportant contribution to the total of cross-market covariance between the U.S. and Japan subportfolios (−4.1) indicates that relatively little hedging occurs between those portfolios. The Global Equity Model assumed that the industry tilts within the U.S. and Japan subportfolios canceled one another. The Global Equity Model Version 2.0 is skeptical of this cancellation.


[0247] A Second Case Study


[0248] Let us consider the implication of this study. As we know, the specific risk of a portfolio (measured in variance term) scales as 1/N for N the number of assets in the portfolio. The common factor risk, however, generally does not scale down so quickly with increasing N. As we have seen, the Global Equity Model and the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 differ in their perception of how much common factor risk a portfolio contains. By allowing N to increase, we should be able to dramatize the difference in the two analyses. To demonstrate this effect, we take our investable universe to consist of Banks and Chemicals. We switch from Autos to Chemicals as the Chemical industry is less consolidated than the Auto industry and thus we are able to increase N to a greater degree.


[0249] We construct a case for N=4 and a case for N=74. In the case N=4 the benchmark is:
2225%Fuji Bank25%Shin-Etsu Chemicals25%BankAmerica25%du Pont


[0250] In the case N=74 the benchmark is allocated
2325%Japan Banks25%Japan Chemicals25%U.S. Banks25%U.S. Chemicals


[0251] and the benchmark is capitalization weighted within each subdivision. In both cases the managed portfolio holds the Japan Chemicals and the U.S. Banks contained in the benchmark. The resulting exposures are as given in Table 21 and 22. It will be noted that in both the Global Equity Model and the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 analyses the mean absolute exposures move somewhat towards zero as N increases. For risk indices this effect occurs as the indices are normalized to zero across the estimation universe, so as N increases they tend to move closer to the universe mean, namely 0. For countries in the Global Equity Model the mean asset beta is one, and as the number of assets in the portfolio grows the mean country exposure moves towards one, thus reducing the active country exposure. For industries, as N increases one picks up exposure to more industries through the secondary operations of the firms. Consequently, the mean industry exposure decreases. The total absolute active industry exposure will tend to increase, however. The summary risk decomposition is given in Table 22. In both cases the specific risk decreases by 88%, exactly as expected from the increase in N. In the Global Equity Model risk index and country risk both decrease by 60-70% resulting in a similar decrease in common factor risk. In the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 risk index risk decreases more, by 80%. However, industry risk actually increases by 33%, and so common factor risk decreases by only 54%. In the N=4 case the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 common factor risk started out as 5.8 times larger than the Global Equity Model common factor risk. Because the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 common factor risk decreases less with increasing N, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 common factor risk ends up 8.9 times larger than the Global Equity Model common factor risk. For specific risk, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 estimate starts out 1.5 times larger than the Global Equity Model estimate. Since the specific risk declines nearly equally with increasing N in both analyses, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 specific risk estimate ends up as 1.7 times the Global Equity Model estimate. Finally, the total risk estimate moves from being twice as large with the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 to being 3.4 times larger than the Global Equity Model estimate. Thus, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 sees 90 units of risk versus the Global Equity Model's estimate of 27 units. In units of standard definition per annum, the Global Equity Model Version 2.0 sees a 33% risk versus the Global Equity Model's estimate of an 18% risk. The differences in the analyses are indeed dramatic.
24TABLE 21Global Equity Model Version 2.0 Risk Exposures(as of April 1998)Small PortfolioLarge PortfolioJapan Local FactorsGrowth0.820.30specific variability−0.74−0.28foreign sensitivity0.690.58systematic variability−0.66−0.18success0.440.20interest rate sensitivity−0.32−0.18value0.300.34size−0.18−0.38financial leverage−0.120.11trading activity−0.060.05city bank−0.25−0.12regional bank0.00−0.20industrial bank0.00−0.08chemicals0.120.28textiles0.000.067 other industries0.000.06Mean Absolute:risk index exposure0.430.26industry exposure0.060.13US Local Factorsearnings yield0.160.07financial leverage0.150.15currency sensitivity−0.12−0.06earnings variablity0.120.18size0.110.33growth0.110.20trading activity0.04−0.005value−0.03−0.07volatility0.03−0.06momentum0.030.11yield0.02−0.01size non-linearity0.010.07bank0.36thrift0.000.04chemicals−0.20−0.33home products0.00−0.02food0.00−0.01mining0.00−0.01oil refining−0.06−0.0074 other industries0.00−0.02Mean Absolute:risk index exposure0.080.11industry exposure0.030.10


[0252]

25





TABLE 22








Risk Decomposition


(variance per month × 10,000, as of April 1998)


















Global Equity Model



Model
Version 2.0
Global Equity Model













Case
small
large
% change
small
large
% change





common factor risk


country


0
12.4
3.8
−64


industry
39
52
33
0.0
0.0
0


risk index
74
15
−80
6.2
2.4
−61


covariances
9
−11
−222
2.4
0.1
−96


total
122
56
−54
21
6.3
−70


specific risk
290
34
−88
188
20.2
−89


total risk
412
90
−78
207
26.5
−87















Global Equity






Model Version 2.0 risk/



Global Equity Model risk
small
large
% change







common factor risk
5.8
8.9
53



specific risk
1.5
1.7
 9



total risk
2.0
3.4
71











[0253] Although the invention is described herein with reference to the preferred embodiment, one skilled in the art will readily appreciate that other applications may be substituted for those set forth herein without departing from the spirit and scope of the present invention. Accordingly, the invention should only be limited by the claims included below.


Claims
  • 1. A method for combining two or more risk models to create a risk model with wider scope than its constituent parts. The method insures that the combined risk model is consistent with the component models from which it is formed. The method consists of the following steps: letting C1 denote a class of algorithms for constructing estimates of a covariance matrices from time histories of data; letting C2 denote a class of asset classes; for x in C2 let C3(x),denoting a class of multi-factor risk models for x; for y in C3(x) denoting its parts as follows: factor exposures X(y,t) at time t; factor returns f(y,t) at time t; and specific covariance matrix D(y,t) at time t; factor covariance matrix F(y,t) at time t; giving the following components: two or more asset classes x1, . . . , xn, et x denote an asset class which is a union of these given asset classes; for each asset class x1 giving a risk model yi in C3(xi); letting Y(t) be such that the decomposition: 24(f⁡(y1,t)f⁡(y2,t)⋮f⁡(yN,t))⏟f⁡(t)=(Y1⁡(t)Y2⁡(t)⋮YN⁡(t))⏟Y⁡(t)⁢ ⁢g⁡(t)+(φ1⁡(t)φ2⁡(t)⋮φ3⁡(t))⏟φ⁡(t)which results in residuals φ(t) such that correlation (φ1,φj) is nearly zero if i≠j; and constructing a risk model for x as follows: forming X(t)=diag(X(y1,t), . . . , X(yn,t)); forming D(t)=diag(D(y1,t), . . . , D(yn,t)); applying a method from C1 to estimate a covariance matrix G(t) from a history of the g(t)s; and applying an optionally different method from C1 to estimate a covariance matrix Φ(t) from a history the φ(t)s; Then X(t)[Y(t)G(t)Y(t)t+Φ(t)φ(t)]X(t)t+D(t) is a risk model for x. Insure the risk model is consistent with each component, asset class risk model as follows: Let F1(t) be the block diagonal matrix obtained from Y(t)G(t)Y(t)′+Φ(t) by setting all elements to zero except those of the blocks corresponding to each asset class. Each such block represents the covariance among the factors explaining risk for a particular asset class. Let F2(t) be the block diagonal matrix whose blocks contain the asset class factor covariance matrices, F(y1,t) in the same order as they appear in F1(t); the off-block diagonal elements are zero. Given a real symmetric positive semi-definite matrix M, let M1/2 denote a square root of M so that M1/2(M1/2)=M. There may be several choices for M1/2. Let M−1/2 denote the inverse of M1/2, or in the event that the inverse does not exist, let M−1/2 be the pseudoinverse. Then X(t)(F21/2F1−1/2(Y(t)G(t)Y(t)′+Φ(t))(F21/2F1−1/2)′)X(t)′ is a risk model that is consistent with the component asset class models.
  • 2. A method for combining two or more risk models to create a risk model with wider scope than its constituent parts, comprising the steps of: denoting a class of algorithms for constructing estimates of a covariance matrices from time histories of data; denoting a class of asset classes; denoting a class of multi-factor risk models; and constructing risk models for each asset class as follows: applying a method to estimate a covariance matrix from a history; and combining asset class risk models to form a risk model with broad coverage that is consistent with each asset class model.
  • 3. The method of claim 2, further comprising the step of: applying a different method to estimate a covariance matrix from a history.